Contents

STAG Technical Database

Section 9 Economy

3 December 2013

Version History

Changes since STAG Refresh, May 2008

Change number

Section updated

Date

1

9.3.1 Agglomeration economies

September 2008

2

New section 9.3.5.1 Agglomeration benefits - zonal method (previously 9.3.1)

September 2008

3

New section 9.3.5.2 Agglomeration benefits - APARC method (previously 9.3.5.1)

September 2008

4

New section 9.3.5.3 Competition Impacts (previously 9.3.5.2)

September 2008

5

9.5.18 Vehicle operating costs (fuel)

September 2008

6

9.5.19 Rates of change in fuel VOCs

September 2008

7

9.2.2.1 and 9.5.23 - Rail Appraisal - Road Network Effects

December 2008

8

9.3.6 - Reporting Wider Economic Benefits

December 2008

9

9.5.18 Vehicle operating costs (fuel)

April 2009

10

9.5.19 Rates of change in fuel VOCs

April 2009

11

9.5.22 Rail operating costs

April 2009

12

9.2.2.9 Reliability benefits

December 2009

13

9.2.2.8 Quality benefits

December 2009

14

9.2.2.4 User benefits - values of time

December 2009

15

9.3.3 Increased output in imperfectly competitive markets

December 2009

16

9.5.13 Forecast Growth in Values of Time

April 2012

17

9.5.18 Vehicle operating costs (fuel and electricity)

April 2012

18

9.2.2.2 Traffic growth

April 2012

19

9.2 Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE)

April 2012

20

9.5.13 Forecast Growth in Values of Time

November 2012

21

9.5.6 Units of Account

November 2012

22

9.5.18 Vehicle operating costs (fuel and electricity)

November 2012

23

9.2.2.3 Growth in Public Transport Patronage

November 2012

24

9.2.2.9 Journey Time Reliability Benefits

December 2013

Contents

9. Economy
9.1 Introduction
9.1.1 Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE)
9.1.2 Wider Economic Benefits
9.1.3 Economic Activity and Location Impacts (EALIs)
9.2 Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE)
9.2.1 Principles of TEE analysis
9.2.2 Calculation of TEE Inputs
9.3 Wider Economic Benefits
9.3.1 Agglomeration economies
9.3.2 Increased competition as a result of better transport
9.3.3 Increased output in imperfectly competitive markets
9.3.4 Wider benefits arising from improved labour supply
9.3.5 Calculation of Wider Economic Benefits
9.3.6 Reporting of Wider Economic Benefits
9.4 Economic Activity and Location Impacts (EALI)
9.4.1 Presentation of EALIs
9.4.2 EALIs as the Rationale for a Transport Project
9.4.3 The Basis of Analysis of EALIs
9.4.4 Part 2 AST - Identification and Quantification
9.4.5 Further Technical Guidance
9.4.6 Additional Guidance for Part 2 AST
9.5 Appraisal Parameters
9.5.1 Appraisal Period
9.5.2 Inflation
9.5.3 Discounting
9.5.4 Discount Rates
9.5.5 Base Year for Discounting
9.5.6 Units of Account
9.5.7 Price Base Year
9.5.8 Model Base Year
9.5.9 Forecasts
9.5.10 Opening Year
9.5.11 Forecast Year
9.5.12 Values of Time
9.5.13 Forecast Growth in Values of Time
9.5.14 Vehicle Occupancies
9.5.15 Journey Purpose Splits
9.5.16 Values of Time Per Vehicle
9.5.17 Vehicle Operating Costs (VOC)
9.5.18 Vehicle Operating Costs (Fuel and electricity)
9.5.19 Rates of Change in Fuel VOCs
9.5.20 Vehicle Operating Costs (Non-Fuel)
9.5.21 Bus Operating Costs
9.5.22 Rail Operating Costs
9.5.23 Rail Appraisal - Road Network Effects
9.6 Reporting

9. Economy

The Part 2 Appraisal against the Economy Criterion has three sub-criteria which together should summarise the full extent of economic impacts. These are:

  • Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE)- the benefits ordinarily captured by standard cost- benefit analysis- the transport impacts of an option;
  • Wider Economic Benefits (WEBs)- relates to the notion of wider economic benefits derived from the impact of transport upon agglomeration, and the underlying relationship of impacts of agglomeration upon productivity; and
  • Economic Activity and Location Impacts (EALIs)- allows the impacts of an option to be expressed in terms of their net effects on the local and/or national economy.

9.1 Introduction

There are two elements to the Economy Criterion - improving the economic efficiency of transport and improving the efficiency of economic activities.

In general terms, economics is the analysis of scarce resources which have alternative uses. If an economic system is Pareto efficient, then it is the case that no one person or group can be made better off without another being made worse off. In the STAG Appraisal the Economy Criterion is concerned primarily with maximising the net benefits, in resource terms, of the provision of transport. This requires maximising consumer surplus by maximising the difference between the willingness to pay of transport users and the resource costs of the provision, operation and maintenance of transport facilities - consumer surplus being measured by the difference between the maximum which an individual transport user is willing to pay to travel and the actual cost of that journey. Therefore, consumer surplus is increased when travel time, operating costs and transfer payments, such as fares, are reduced and when more transport users are able to travel due to the reduction in costs.

The impact of a transport infrastructure project on the economy is assessed via a Transport Economic Efficiency Analysis (TEE) and an Economic Activity and Location Impact (EALI) study. The Wider Economic Benefits (WEB) of a transport option, measured in terms of the additional benefits to economic development, are considered as a separate sensitivity test.

9.1.1 Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE)

The TEE analysis captures the main impacts of an option in terms of economic welfare, as represented by the main costs and benefits of users and operators of the transport system. These impacts are expressed in terms of monetary values, by Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA), which are added together and discounted to produce a Net Present Value (NPV). Costs to the public sector are itemised separately (see Section 12 Cost to Government).

The TEE analysis presents the key effects disaggregated by particular groups, mode of transport, and by impact (time, vehicle operating costs etc.). In addition to a statement of aggregate impact (NPV, BCR), section 9.2.2.1 now requires the classification of journey time savings by the size.

A TEE analysis should be presented for each option and should demonstrate the change in costs and benefits for each option relative to the do-minimum case.

9.1.2 Wider Economic Benefits

The Economy Criterion is also concerned with improving the efficiency of economic activities. The transport costs and benefits captured by the TEE are intended to represent an acceptable approximation of the full economic impacts of a project, expressed in terms of economic welfare. However, it has been suggested that the benefits, generated through CBA, fail to capture the additional wider benefits of improved transport provision to economic development. The SACTRA (1999) report on Transport and the Economy considered in some detail the extent to which these issues are relevant and commissioned further research.

This research has come to fruition and the approach taken by STAG is to calculate these wider economic benefits (WEBs) as a sensitivity to the TEE results. The main reason for inclusion as a sensitivity is one of evaluation and monitoring - the methodology is such that it is very difficult to monitor or evaluate the benefits captured by WEBs.

Detail on the methodology to be used is presented in Section 9.3

9.1.3 Economic Activity and Location Impacts (EALIs)

Transport projects have the potential to impact upon economic performance at the local level and may influence demand for the location of economic and other activities.

Whilst the TEE and WEBs aim to capture the net economic benefits of a project at the national level, the EALI is more concerned with the spatial distribution of these national impacts to allow an assessment of the impact on the local economy. The EALI complements the TEE and WEB but does not generally identify additional economic impacts that could be added to the TEE and WEB results. Generally the EALI will restate the TEE and WEB impacts using narrower measures of economic welfare.

The nature of EALI analysis is currently subject to a review arising from the inclusion of WEBs within STAG. The current position is that WEBs refine the TEE analysis and may involve issues of double counting with EALIs. However, as TEE/WEB and EALI results are presented separately, the current view is that they represent different ways of representing the same information.

Practitioners may take the view that the inclusion of WEBs, which is a relatively arduous process may reduce the need for EALI analysis. This issue is currently under review; however, the view of Transport Scotland is that EALI analysis remains important as a tool for analysing the distributional impacts of transport, but that the resources committed to it may be reduced with the incorporation of WEBs.

The EALI component remains particularly important in assessing the distributional impact of an option and is particularly relevant to assessing how far a transport project might support regeneration policy objectives in a particular area. Where EALI impacts are expected to be significant, it is suggested that EALIs are assessed directly and presented separately using GDP and/or employment measures.

EALIs must be presented at the Scotland level, and consequently must include both local, or intra-area, impacts and inter-area impacts. Both the positive and negative impacts attributable to a scheme must be identified, including any displacement effects.

The EALI is particularly relevant to assessing how far a transport project might support regeneration policy objectives in a particular area.

9.2 Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE)

The Transport Economic Efficiency (TEE) Analysis provides guidance on how to assess the contribution which a transport option may have on economic welfare through consideration of the resultant transport costs and benefits. The transport costs and benefits captured by the TEE, and collated into an NPV, are intended to represent an acceptable approximation of the full economic impacts of a project, expressed in terms of economic welfare. It provides guidance on the principles which underpin the general approach to be followed and outlines issues and methodologies relating to different sub-criteria. Practitioners must follow this guidance and if required request advice from Transport Scotland on technical matters relating to the appraisal parameters. It should be noted that the method set out is broadly consistent with that previously specified by the Department for Transport (WebTAG) but has some key differences in the scope of impacts and in the interpretation of outputs.

Following the 1999 SACTRA report and work carried forward by DfT, the TEE analysis is now supplemented by Wider Economic Benefits (WEBs) analysis and this methodology is detailed in section 9.3.

9.2.1 Principles of TEE analysis

The central principle of transport economic efficiency analysis is to estimate the welfare gain which results from transport investment, as measured by the individual's willingness to pay for such an improvement and the financial impact on private sector transport operators. Willingness to pay should be consistent with the demand response to the improved transport opportunities.

The accepted best measure of welfare gain is the change in consumer surplus enjoyed by individuals and the change in producer surplus/deficit accruing to transport suppliers. Consumer surplus is defined as the benefit that an individual enjoys over and above the cost they would be willing to pay. In transport, cost is defined in money and time terms (usually called generalised cost). Thus, if an individual is currently willing to travel for 15 minutes to enjoy an activity and a transport option reduces that to 10 minutes then the time saving of 5 minutes is an accurate measure of their consumer surplus. However, if new users are attracted to use the facility (either by switching from another mode or by choosing to travel when otherwise they would not have) in response to this time saving, then it is not normally clear at what time cost they would have been willing to switch. Here, the convention is to assume that the switch would have occurred, on average, halfway between the do-minimum and do-something costs. This approximation would attribute 2.5 minutes of benefit to new users in the above example. This approximation normally holds but where a wholly new mode (e.g. light rapid transit) is introduced, further guidance should be sought from the Scottish Government and/or Transport Scotland.

As in all aspects of STAG Appraisal, it is important to demonstrate, in several dimensions, the distributional impacts of a scheme within the overall TEE analysis. These include:

  • Spatial impacts: how benefits and costs fall across the area of analysis or the modelled area. It should be noted that this is distinct from the spatial distributional impacts analysed in the EALI analysis.
  • Socio-economic impacts: how benefits fall to different groups of the population.
  • Provider/user impacts: how benefits/costs fall to public transport providers and/or users. For example, a rise in fares will reduce the consumer surplus of existing travellers (and discourage some from travelling by this mode) but will represent a benefit to the public transport provider, assuming demand is inelastic.
  • User group impacts: how benefits and costs fall to motorists and/or users of public transport services.
  • Time savings impacts: the distribution of journey time changes by size of those time savings.

The relative importance of different types of distributional effects will depend on the option being appraised. Where public transport operators are affected, the breakdown of costs and revenues by mode should be undertaken.

Presentation of journey time impacts by size of time saving is obligatory where a transport model has been undertaken to inform the appraisal.

The results of economic appraisals should be expressed in the market price unit of account (see section 9.5 Appraisal Parameters), i.e. including indirect taxes. This is consistent with the willingness to pay principle underpinning the calculation of benefits.

9.2.2 Calculation of TEE Inputs

Guidance for the calculation of TEE inputs is provided via the attached links.

9.2.2.1 Benefits to Transport Users

The economic benefits of transport projects are often captured through an analysis of the impacts on transport users. Benefits to users often fall into the following sub-groups:

  • Transport users whose travel patterns do not change but who enjoy time saving and/or other benefits;
  • Diverting users, who switch from other routes because of changes in relative (generalised) costs;
  • Diverting users who switch mode in response to changes in relative (generalised) costs;
  • Generated users, whose use was previously frustrated by, for example, traffic conditions on the option, route or service; and
  • Redistributed users who may change their origin or destination in response to transport changes (for example, finding employment elsewhere).

Benefits typically arise from a combination of the following:

  • Changes in the monetary costs of travel;
  • Journey time savings achieved directly, for example by using a new road or bridge rather than the next best alternative;
  • Improvements in journey time reliability or journey quality, which may be especially important for certain types of users such as delivery services;
  • Improvements in journey time reliability or journey quality, such as comfort or reduction in number of interchanges.

Journey time benefits and disbenefits form a key component of transport user benefits. The process to be applied in quantifying and valuing journey time changes is well established and forms the basis for transport modelling. This is described in section 9.2.2.4 and values of time to be used in appraisal can be found in section 9.5.12.

It is acknowledged that this approach may overlook significant differences in the distribution of journey time (dis-) benefits over space and across transport users.

Economic Activity and Locational Impact (EALI) assessment seeks to understand the distribution of benefits over space.

To give greater transparency to the distribution of (dis-) benefits across transport users, appraisers should, in addition to reporting aggregate journey time (dis-) benefits as a component of overall TEE benefits or costs, present journey time changes (as savings) classified by size. Six size classifications are recommended. This data is produced by the UK Department for Transport's "Transport User Benefit Analysis" (TUBA) software program version 1.8 onwards. The information should be presented as shown below:

Size of time saving Total journey time savings (mins) Total monetised journey time savings (£m, %, 2002 prices)

Classification

Work trips

% total journey time Non-work trips % total journey time

Work trips

% Non-work trips %
< -5 mins

**

**

**

**

**

**

**

**

-5 to -2 mins

**

**

**

**

>-2 to 0 mins

**

**

**

**

0 to <+2 mins

**

**

**

**

+2 to +5 mins

**

**

**

**

>5 mins

**

**

**

**

** Data should be provided for the 1st modelled year (after scheme opening) and for the entire appraisal period. These outputs are available from TUBA version 1.8 onwards.

While the classification and presentation of journey time changes by size provides the decision-maker with an understanding of the distribution or equity of journey time as savings among users, this does not exclude projects which do not offer journey time savings nor imply a preference for projects which result in a large number of small journey time savings. Furthermore, journey time savings should continue to be monetised using the standard equity values of time laid out in tables 9.7 and 9.8 until such time as the evidence for the value of small time savings versus large time savings is better established.

As transport projects form part of a system or network, network-wide effects should be considered. This can help show whether transport users of other modes or routes gain if an option is implemented. Network effects which will give rise to benefits to non users include:

  • Reduction in journey times on other routes which arise because of some users of the other route(s) switching to the new route or switching mode;
  • Improvements in journey time reliability and other aspects of journey quality, arising for similar reasons.

These impacts may be reduced as changes in travel conditions are likely to generate additional traffic on other routes, so that, for example, time savings generated as some users switch routes are reduced, while suppressed demand is released on the other routes. These effects also need to be assessed where they are likely to be significant.

These impacts, which occur outwith or external to the option under consideration, need to be identified at an early stage in the Part 2 Appraisal. Where these are likely to be important in relation to the costs and other benefits of the option, they should be quantified in the same manner as direct benefits and costs. Further guidance on how to calculate these effects is provided in Section 9.5.23.

9.2.2.2 Traffic Growth

The starting point for the assessment of road traffic growth should be the Scottish Trip End Programme (STEP) or, alternatively, the DfT database TEMPRO-NTEM. STEP provides local growth factors consistent with future land-use plans in Scotland. The socio-economic data which forms inputs to the model (population, employment etc.) and STEP are consistent with those used in TEMPRO-NTEM.

However, the factors highlighted in the following paragraphs will also need to be considered on a project specific basis.

It is necessary to make forecasts of traffic growth which distinguish and take account of:

  • Growth in demand which will occur in the network whether or not the particular project is undertaken;
  • Specific generated traffic growth, which should be treated where possible in a dynamic rather than static framework;
  • Collateral traffic growth/generation, i.e. growth due to specific additional activity, defined below.

Provided land-use plans are not dependent on the transport option, then STEP should be the best source of information for the first of these forecasts.

Where forecasts are required to take account of generated traffic growth or in the presence of dependent housing or land use developments, it is recommended that practitioners consult the LATIS service.

If practitioners wish to adopt growth forecasts other than those derived from STEP or TEMPRO-NTEM, they should discuss alternative options with the Scottish Government, Transport Scotland or other relevant funding agency at the earliest opportunity.

In addition to the release and subsequent growth of demand (generated traffic or patronage), options may give rise to factors which alter the overall demand for travel at each level of generalised cost - a shift of the demand curve. This is here termed collateral traffic growth, in order to avoid confusion with the concept of induced traffic growth, which typically refers to direct or indirect generated traffic.

Collateral effects need to be identified and, where important, quantified. These effects are derived from a chain of cause and effect in which the transport option changes the parameters which determine the level of demand at local or national level, and can take place for a number of reasons, including:

  • Land-use effects, for example where the transport investment would open up otherwise unavailable land resources for industrial, commercial and residential development;
  • Mobile investment which is attracted because of improved accessibility, involving perhaps additional workers and/or the attraction of industries which raise local/regional incomes, leading to additional traffic.

These effects are traffic effects but take place through what are termed EALIs - economic activity and location impacts. As discussed below in the section 9.4 on EALIs, the essential first step is to identify the EALIs and the rationale for them, then to assess their implications for demand for travel.

9.2.2.3 Growth in Public Transport Patronage

Projected trends in public transport patronage should be considered with particular reference to local time-series trends. Practitioners may also wish to take account of:

  • Industry projections of growth (for example for the rail network); and
  • Forecasts produced by multi-modal area-wide models, such as TMfS.

If growth in public transport patronage is of particular importance for the option under consideration, practitioners may wish to consider developing bespoke public transport growth models. In such circumstances practitioners should discuss their methodology with Transport Scotland or other relevant funding agency.

Where demand forecasting in rail is necessary, Transport Scotland believe that it is not reasonable to expect that demand will grow infinitely and that there should be a cap on rail demand growth. For the purposes of appraisal, demand should be capped in 2032, unless there is a clear argument and explanation of why a different cap has been used.

9.2.2.4 User Benefits - Values of Time

An important factor in the assessment of the transport options is the impact on the time spent travelling, for both personal travel and freight. In order to include these impacts in the estimation of user benefits, it is necessary to put a money value on time savings. In the appraisal process, the general premise is that the value of resources used or saved is reflected in their market prices. This is the principle underlying the valuation of working time savings. However, in the case of non-working time savings, in general there is no market in which time can be traded for money, and therefore no directly observable market price exists. Instead, values are derived from users' willingness to trade money for time, obtained from either revealed preference (RP) or stated preference (SP) surveys.

The standard values of time and the factors for up-rating them are presented in Section 9.5.12.

In a multi-modal or public transport context, there is the complication that non-business travellers do not value time spent walking to or waiting for public transport at the same rate as time spent travelling in the vehicle. This disutility is different for 'commuting' and 'other' journeys. Time spent waiting for public transport services should be valued at two and a half times the value of non-working 'commuting' and 'other' time respectively; time spent in interchange on journeys on public transport should be valued at two times the value of 'commuting' and 'other' time respectively. Where an option may be specifically designed to enhance the waiting environment (for example a bus station) then local surveys to measure disutility and willingness to pay for improvements may be valuable to modify this approach. This may be particularly useful where this represents the main justification for an option.

This issue of wait time is of particular importance when appraising changes to ferry services or their replacement with fixed links. Scheduling costs are defined as the welfare cost imposed upon activity scheduling by transport constraints. Scheduling costs arise as transport constraints prevent activities being undertaken at the desired time or for the desired duration. Such scheduling costs, like travel time costs, form an disincentive to travel and therefore improvements in transport quality - through improved frequency of service - can reduce scheduling costs and improve the overall economic benefit of a transport improvement option. Scheduling costs are more relevant where headways are long and operating hours are short (before the proposed transport improvement) than where services are reasonably frequent and operating hours are also reasonable. Restrictions in departure time choices that will be the primary driver for scheduling costs. Any change in time spent waiting, which is taken as half the service interval, should be included and valued as set out above.

There is also evidence that travellers are willing to pay to avoid interchange between modes in addition to the reduction in time spent waiting for the subsequent leg of the journey.

This 'interchange penalty' must be included in changes to benefits. The factor to allow for this disutility will normally lie in a range between 3 minutes and 15 minutes for urban travel, depending on the quality of the interchange and the distribution of perceptions of users, which can vary widely. Research commissioned by the Scottish Government derived values of 4.5 minutes for bus users and 8 minutes for rail users, each based on research in large cities. 1 For interurban rail travel, the value will be higher. The use of an appropriate value should be justified either through establishing local values through research or with recourse to comparable examples elsewhere. Practitioners should be careful not to double-count time spent waiting for a connecting service within an appropriate interchange penalty.

9.2.2.5 Indirect Taxation Adjustments

All costs and benefits should be quoted in market prices (see Appraisal Parameters Section 9.5.6). The market price values of time for working time include a mark up for indirect taxes of 19.0%, which is equivalent to the average rate of indirect taxation in the UK economy. For non-working time, the benefit is perceived by the individual and is therefore inclusive of indirect tax. These market price values should be used as set out in Section 9.5.6.

In disaggregating the impacts upon user groups, allocations of financial impacts between Government and others is required. For example, a saving in fuel costs for drivers should be valued at current market prices (i.e. including fuel duty), but on the other side of the equation the loss of tax revenue to Government needs to be taken into account. Practitioners should refer to Section 12 Costs to Government.

9.2.2.6 User Charges

In general terms, any additional charges paid should be treated as a cost to travellers (i.e. a negative value in the AST) and a reduction in charges should be treated as a benefit. For users who switch mode from car to public transport, the additional fare paid will be a disbenefit to the car user, but they will also make a financial gain in terms of savings in vehicle operating costs.

9.2.2.7 Changes in Vehicle Operating Costs

Transport proposals can generate changes in the operating costs incurred by the user. Vehicle operating costs are defined as costs that vary with vehicle usage and are based on vehicle-miles travelled. These costs include fuel, tyres, oil, maintenance, repairs, and mileage-dependent depreciation. This comes about due to changes in the volume of car travel, both through mode switching or induced traffic, and in the speed and distance travelled as a result of route changes.

Vehicle Operating Cost (VOC) calculations should be consistent with the parameters included in Section 9.5.17. This incorporates future changes in the resource cost of fuel and in vehicle efficiency.

9.2.2.8 Quality Benefits

Journey quality could be considered as an important determinant of travel behaviour. For example, it is reasonable to expect that poor journey quality could act as a deterrent to mode or route choice or as a disincentive to make a journey. Travel decisions may be based on the weakest link in the journey and addressing poor quality travel elements may therefore remove barriers to travel.

In transport appraisal there is a debate as to whether willingness to pay for quality benefits should be included in the TEE analysis. However, it is invariably the case that the costs of quality improvements are subsumed within option costs. By not including perceived benefits, there would be a problem of bias against those options that have an explicit objective to improve quality. Willingness to pay for quality benefits has been investigated through stated preference research but the absence of definitive values for quality improvements persists. Consequently, quality benefits should be assessed qualitatively in the TEE analysis.

9.2.2.9 Journey Time Reliability Benefits

The measurement, assessment and valuation of journey time reliability has gained increasing recognition as the potential contribution of projects to improved journey time reliability has been realised, most notably, in the case of Intelligent Transport Systems (ITS) projects.

Travellers are sensitive to the consequences, such as prolonged waiting times, missed connections and arrival at the destination either before or after the desired or expected arrival time. Over time, there is evidence to suggest journey time unreliability, valued more highly than journey time, can itself become predictable and, correctly or incorrectly influence traveller mode or route choice.

Evidence suggests that travellers value changes in excess travel time (i.e. late running) higher than changes in scheduled travel time and that the value of journey time depends on the probability of delay.

Scoping

Transport Scotland recognize that the calculation of reliability benefits can be resource intensive, depending on the modelling tools which practitioners have available. As such, it is important that the need to undertake an assessment of reliability benefits is properly scoped at Part One Appraisal, to ensure that the resource dedicated to the analysis is proportionate to the requirements of the study and the scale of the expected impacts.

Definitions

Journey time reliability is defined as the variation in journey time that drivers or passengers cannot predict. It arises from random and non-random effects as follows:

  • Day to day variability- variability in congestion in the same period every day;
  • Variability due to random events including incidents, accidents etc

Appraisal is normally concerned with journey time unreliability as a problem or issue to be measured and addressed. Conversely, the assessment of potential improvements to journey time reliability forms the basis for the evaluation of benefits associated with a project.

Public Transport Journey Time Reliability measurement and evaluation

Reliability in the context of public transport is conceived of in terms of "lateness" defined as the difference between travellers' actual and timetabled arrival times. Note, early arrivals are ignored in the valuation of public transport journey time reliability. In the case of rail, early arrivals are recorded but not used in the calculation of Passenger Performance Measures (PPM).

Two measures of lateness must be considered: average lateness; and the variability of lateness, measured by the standard deviation of lateness. To assess these and the number of passengers affected, data from a number of sources is required:

  • Service timetables;
  • Service headways;
  • Recorded delay information;
  • Passenger Performance Measures (PPM) for relevant rail routes and operators;
  • Proportion of rail services subject to delay;
  • Estimates of current and forecast passenger demand by origin-destination (or journey length) and journey purpose for relevant services and routes with and without the project.

A measure of rail performance must also examine the rate of cancelled services or reliability. To make allowance for the total lateness caused by cancelled trains we usually multiply the service interval by 1.5. This cancellation factor is in line with the notion that in this case the delay impacts on waiting rather than in-vehicle time. Waiting time incurs higher disutility than in-vehicle time because of the additional discomfort involved. The resulting lateness should then be multiplied by the lateness factor of 3 to capture the full costs of poor performance.

Therefore a central lateness factor of three, which includes the uplift of 20% for a change in variability, should be used in the general case. Where sufficient evidence can be provided to justify the application of a different lateness factor a value higher or lower than 3 should be adopted. In the general case one minute of average lateness is valued by passengers as being equivalent to three minutes of scheduled journey time. This conversion to scheduled journey time allows us to place a monetary value on reliability using the appropriate value of time.

Where no delay data is available for an intermediate station the analyst should use delay data from the final destination. In this case it may be appropriate to use a different lateness factor. But a robust rationale should be provided for any departure from the recommended central factor of 3.

The Passenger Demand Forecasting Handbook (PDFH) provides guidance for the measurement and valuation of lateness and unpredictable delay affecting rail passengers and the assessment of the impact of rail projects upon journey time reliability.

To estimate the monetised benefit of changes in the variability of lateness (for public transport), money values are needed. The concept of the reliability ratio enables changes in variability of lateness or of journey time to be expressed in monetary terms. The reliability ratio is defined as:

Reliability Ratio = Value of SD of lateness / Value of lateness.

Broadly, the value of average lateness for public transport is expected to be the same as the value of time spent waiting for public transport, that is, at 2.5 times the value of in-vehicle time; the value of the reliability ratio ranges from 0.6 to 1.5 for public and about 0.8 for private passenger travel.

For the purposes of appraisal, the recommended reliability ratio values are shown below:

Journey Purpose

Mode

Reliability ratio

All

Train

1.4

All

Bus/Tram/Metro

1.4

If the reliability ratio has a value of, for example 0.5, then a 1 minute reduction in the standard deviation of delay is equivalent to a 0.5 minute reduction in mean delay.

Given that it is rare that we ever have a complete knowledge of the delay distribution with which to calculate the standard deviation of journey time, an alternative method can be used. 'The Valuation of Reliability for Personal Travel', Transportation Research Part E 37, Bates, J., Polak, J., Jones, P and A. Cook (2001) suggested that it is the "pure" lateness effect which tends to dominate the calculations, because the effect of variability is less important given that rail passengers have already made some "compromises" in selecting arrival or departure time of their preferred scheduled train.

Indeed, as noted earlier, some travellers may find that variability brings them closer to their preferred arrival time than an "on-time" arrival would. Consequently a 20% uplift of the lateness factor is an acceptable proxy for the additional disutility incurred as a result of variability in delay.

Road Journey Time Reliability measurement and evaluation

The preferred measure of journey time reliability for drivers and passengers on the road network is the standard deviation in travel time for a particular hour/period of the day. This, by definition, assumes travel times are normally distributed. Reliability can be usefully stated as the coefficient of variation; the ratio of the standard deviation of journey time and average journey time for a particular hour/period of the day. This can be complemented by an assessment of reliability, which may reflect:

  • the consequences for subsequent activities should unexpected variability arise;
  • the likelihood of encountering an incident which reduces capacity and
  • other implicit effects which cause unreliability and variability in the average journey times.

The current standard deviation of journey times on a route-by-route basis can be calculated using observed data from a range of sources including bluetooth and floating vehicle journey time data and from data automatic traffic counters (see section 2.4.1)

The appraisal of transport schemes or policies should aim to place a value on any changes to unpredictable journey time variability because of the extra costs it incurs on drivers and passengers.

To estimate the monetised benefit of changes in the variability of journey time (for private road vehicles), money values are needed. The concept of the reliability ratio enables changes in variability of lateness or of journey time to be expressed in monetary terms. The reliability ratio is defined as:

Reliability Ratio = Value of SD of travel time / Value of travel time

Using a standard value of time, the value of the standard deviation of journey times can be calculated using the recommend reliability ratio values below.

Journey Purpose

Mode

Reliability ratio

Commuting/Business/Other

Car

0.8

The way in which the change in the level of JTV is forecast will, in the light of current knowledge, vary according to the context. Different methodologies have been developed for inter urban motorway and dual carriageway roads, urban roads, and other roads, as discussed below.

In appraising travel time reliability on highway schemes, it is important to distinguish whether the scheme being appraised is an Urban Road (defined usually as having a speed limit of 30 or 40 miles per hour) or Inter Urban Road (which usually have a speed limit of 50 plus miles per hour). On Inter Urban Roads it is also important to further distinguish between Motorway roads; Dual carriageway roads and single carriageway roads.

Inter Urban Motorway and Dual Carriageway Variability

Research has shown that as long as demand is below capacity, incidents will be the main source of JTV, and DTDV is much less important except in urban areas where the two effects cannot be readily separated. The additional delays caused by congestion unrelated to incidents and any associated variability can be assumed to be allowed for in the journey time forecasts. However, in the case of delays due to incidents a separate element for average delays will usually need to be added to the variability element.

INCA (Incident Cost Benefit Analysis) enables the estimation of the monetised benefits of measures affecting journey time variability covering incidents on motorways and dual carriageways. INCA requires substantial inputs from a suitable transport or traffic model of the scheme being appraised. The INCA model derivation assumes a dual carriageway layout and the parameters are based on data for motorways only. It is therefore not suitable for single carriageways, though the model may be used for dual carriageways as well as motorways. The resulting estimates of benefits cannot be taken to be as robust as those for time savings or accident reductions, for example.

The outputs of INCA reflect how delays caused by incidents may vary according to the severity and length of the incident, the number of lanes blocked and the volume of traffic at the time. Changing the number of lanes available to traffic changes both the probability of encountering an incident (or its aftermath) and the delays caused by incidents

For motorways and dual carriageways, alternative routes avoiding particular sections usually have limited capacity making it difficult for large numbers of drivers to divert if they encounter delays due to an incident. In the absence of significant "transient excess demand" (temporary periods of demand exceeding capacity), incidents are the main source of unpredictable variability and INCA should be used. Practitioners should refer to the latest release note and model documentation prior to use.

Urban Road Variability

Models predicting journey time variability from all sources have been developed for urban areas. In such areas alternative routes are more readily available than on motorways and there are many ways for drivers to divert away from incidents which reduce capacity on a particular route. This affects the relative importance of incident and day to day variability (DTDV) effects.

A generalised model has been developed which permits the forecasting of the Standard Deviation of Journey Time for urban roads.

The model takes, as input, forecast Journey Time (t) and Distance (d) for each origin to destination flow. These can be estimated or taken from a suitable transport or traffic model. The model is subject to the assumption that the distribution of trip distances (alternatively, Origin-Destination distances within the demand matrices) and free-flow speeds do not change as a result of the scheme.

The change in journey time variability (represented by Δσij) is given by:

Δσij = 0.0018 (t ij2 2.02 - tij1 2.02) dij -1.41

Where

  • tij1 and tij2 are the journey times for the journey from i to j (seconds) between the Do Minimum/Reference Case ("before") and the Do Something ("after").
  • Δσij is the change in standard deviation of journey time for the journey from i to j (seconds) between the Do Minimum/Reference Case ("before") and the Do Something ("after").
  • dij is the journey distance from i to j (km)

The reliability benefit applying the rule of a half is therefore calculated using:

Mathematical Equation

Note that the value of reliability (VOR) is obtained by multiplying the value of time by the reliability ratio and Tij1 and Tij2 are number of trips before and after the change.

The model permits the calculation of reliability benefits for travellers with different journey purposes and corresponding trip length distributions.

Although the model above can be used to estimate the effect of schemes and their reliability benefits in urban areas, a locally calibrated model or at least a local validation is preferable.

Other Road Types

For journeys predominantly on single carriageways outside urban areas, it is not currently possible to estimate monetised reliability benefits.

Assessing journey time reliability benefits in multi-modal environments

For multi modal studies, highway and public transport reliability should be measured and appraised separately, employing the methods currently available for each mode.

Reporting Reliability

Journey time reliability benefits should be identified separately from the standard TEE benefits, and not included as part of the core NPV or BCR. They should be reported and details included within the ASTs.

9.2.2.10 Impacts on Private Sector Operators

Impacts on private sector transport providers should be recorded in the TEE analysis. These include changes in investment costs, operating and maintenance costs, operator revenues and grant/subsidy payments. In all instances the cost included should be adjusted for optimism bias (see section 13.3).

Financial costs (and benefits) to the Government should not be included in the TEE assessment. These impacts are covered in Section 12. The cost to Government should be compared with all of the benefits (i.e. across all five STAG Criteria) in order to assess overall value for money rather than the costs and benefits quantified in the TEE analysis.

9.2.2.11 Revenues

Extra revenue should be treated as a benefit to operators. Revenues are related to user charges, as user charges (fares etc) represent money transfers from users to operators which become revenues from the operator's point of view. However, this does not mean that the economic benefit of changes in user charges is the same to the traveller and the operator. In fact, for travellers, the economic benefit of a change in charges is the resultant change in their consumer surplus. For those who do not change their behaviour, the change in consumer surplus is the same as the change in money paid, but for those who do change their behaviour, this is not the case. For operators, however, the economic benefit of a change in charges is simply the change in net revenue received. Therefore, the values for User Charges under User Benefits and the values for Revenues under Private Sector Operator Impacts will usually not be equal in size.

In many cases extra revenues to one operator will to some extent represent a transfer from other operators. For example, a rail investment may lead to modal switch from buses, which represents a loss to bus operators. Where such impacts are likely to be significant, they should be taken into account and the revenue impacts should be disaggregated by mode in order to identify the distributional effects.

9.2.2.12 Investment Costs

These should include all infrastructure costs and vehicle costs incurred by private sector operators which are additional to those incurred in the do-minimum scenario. Fees, design, land acquisition and other preliminary works should be included. Investment costs should always be recorded as a negative entry in the TEE table.

9.2.2.13 Operating and Maintenance Costs

Operating and maintenance costs should include the additional annually recurring costs incurred by the private sector in running and maintaining the facility. Examples of these costs include operating costs for new public transport services, and maintenance costs of vehicles and facilities. Operating and maintenance costs should always be recorded as a negative entry in the TEE table.

9.2.2.14 Grant and Subsidy Payments

In the majority of cases, private sector operator revenues are unlikely to cover the investment and operating costs of an option, and hence some form of grant or subsidy will be required to deliver actions by private sector operators (e.g. First ScotRail, bus operators, etc). Any such grant or subsidy represents a benefit to operators and these should always be recorded as positive amounts in the TEE table.

At the appraisal stage funding agencies are unlikely to be able to give commitments or to be precise about the amounts of support likely to be available. However, the deficit arising from private sector provision without the benefit of grant or subsidy will be indicative of the level of support likely to be required to deliver the strategy or project (although it should be noted that the private sector is likely to require an additional profit margin/return on capital). Consideration should also be given to whether the level of grant or subsidy would be likely to meet the relevant decision criteria published by funding agencies.

There may be a need to disaggregate the market into different operators in order to assess overall subsidy requirements. For example, a rail enhancement may lead to a loss of bus revenue but there will generally be no requirement to compensate the bus operator (although this should still be recorded as a disbenefit to bus operators under "revenues").

In some cases, it may be possible to identify potential developer contributions. In effect, these are 'negative grants', which should be recorded both as a cost to the private sector and a benefit to the public sector (for further guidance please refer to Section 12 Cost to Government). In the TEE table, these appear as negative benefits, while in the Public Accounts table they appear as revenues. Including these contributions in the Public Accounts table clarifies their effect in reducing demands on public funding for schemes, while their inclusion in the TEE table highlights their impact on business.

9.2.2.15 Freight Benefits

The inclusion of freight user benefits should not be used other than those delivered through operating cost and time savings.

Changes to the transport network which impact on freight can affect businesses and the economy in two ways:

  • Cost changes - any change to freight operating costs as a result of a transport intervention is transferred to the recipient and eventually the consumer; and
  • Production changes - changes in freight provision which allow firms to improve their production results in greater output and therefore consumption within the economy.

When assessing the costs and benefits of any potential transport option, the current STAG methodology already takes account of key factors such as the value of time, vehicle operating costs and network characteristics. Consequently, the first impact is already well accounted for in any transport appraisal assuming the correct data defining actual and projected freight traffic is input into the assessment.

The second impact has traditionally been difficult to capture within appraisals and often ignored. It should be pointed out that this was an issue which related not only to freight, but to all travel which affected businesses' daily operation, such as business travel, etc. This impact is now captured under the Wider Economic Benefits of the Economic Appraisal. As a result Transport Scotland continue to believe that that potential freight impacts are appraised to the same standard as all other impacts within the transport appraisal.

9.3 Wider Economic Benefits

The second sub-criterion found under the Economy Criterion, concerns Wider Economic Benefits (WEBs) derived from the impact of transport upon agglomeration, and the underlying relationship of impacts of agglomeration upon productivity.

A set of suggested methodologies for appraisal of Wider Economic Benefits was published by the UK Department for Transport in summer 2005 covering a range of welfare and GDP benefits. Four possible further types of additional transport impacts were identified:

  • WB1 Agglomeration economies
  • WB2 Increased competition as a result of better transport
  • WB3 Increased output in imperfectly competitive markets
  • WB4 Wider benefits arising from improved labour supply

9.3.1 Agglomeration economies

"Economies of agglomeration describe the productivity benefits that some firms derive from being located close to other firms. This could be because proximity to other firms facilitates more sharing of knowledge or because locating close to other firms means access to more suppliers and larger labour markets."2

The methodology employed for measuring a firm's access to markets is 'effective density' (Graham, 2005). Effective density is a measure of the accessibility of zone i to jobs in all zones. The formula for effective density, of zone i, in situation X (X is base, Do-minimum or Do-Something) is given by:

Mathematical Equation

where EjX is the employment in zone j and (gijX)α is the generalised cost of travelling between zone i and j in situation X. The parameter α represents the importance of distance in determining access to markets.

As such, although termed agglomeration benefits, practitioners should not assume that these benefits are exclusive to dense agglomerations, as the theory underlying them, that improved transport provides benefits by giving firms better access to markets and factors of production, applies equally to both areas of high and low initial levels of agglomeration. The name is an indication that benefits area associated with increases in agglomeration, rather any particular base level. Indeed, research suggests that there are diminishing returns to agglomeration, which implies that the greatest potential for a given change in transport costs to result in agglomeration benefits is in areas with a low initial effective density.

As a result, practitioners should not assume that agglomeration benefits will be focussed in urban areas rather than rural ones. Indeed, within agglomerations, which tend to have a very mature transport infrastructure, evidence shows that it is difficult to generate significant changes in the overall cost of travel and as such it is unlikely that any single transport scheme will result in significant changes to effective density in an agglomeration.

In contrast, although more rural areas will tend to have a smaller population exposed to any change in effective density, it is possible to achieve greater changes in transport costs, and therefore more significant changes in effective density, in these areas.

Practitioners should note, however, that any estimated agglomeration benefits will be affected by the assumptions regarding the α parameter. Although current best estimates of the value of α are that it is equal to one, this is an area subject to ongoing research and it is possible that it will be revised in the near future. As such, estimates of agglomeration benefits have a relatively high degree of associated uncertainty, and are to be treated as a sensitivity to the standard TEE analysis. Further detail on the calculation of agglomeration benefits and the parameters to be used is given in Section 9.3.5.

9.3.2 Increased competition as a result of better transport

Benefits arising from increased competition as a result of transport improvements (WB2) was identified by DfT as theoretically possible. The current position at DfT is that there is little evidence to be found on the relationship between transport and competition and on the basis of that available, DfT does not expect that there will be significant wider benefits owing to increased competition.

There is a view among analysts in Transport Scotland that due to geographical reasons this may not be the case within certain parts of Scotland.In the absence of further information, the current position is that WB2 be treated as neutral.

9.3.3 Increased output in imperfectly competitive markets

"Where there is imperfect competition in a market, we've seen that the value placed on additional production, the price, is normally higher than production costs. Firms and consumers would therefore be jointly better off if firms were to increase production. If better transport induces firms to increase production there are precisely such benefits … the value attached to time savings would underestimate the true benefits."3

As set out by the DfT (2005) WB3 is calculated on the basis of an "uprate factor" V applied to the direct cost savings to firms, i.e. business time savings (BTS) and reliability gains (RG).

where V is an uplift factor based on price-cost margins. The simple and recommended way of calculating this benefit is to apply an appropriate uplift to business user benefits. At present this uplift is 10% in almost all cases.

Recent research commissioned by Transport Scotland has indicated that price cost margins are likely to be higher in rural areas. 4 In such situations, it is reasonable to apply a higher uplift. For schemes in very remote rural areas, defined in accordance with the Scottish Government 8-fold urban rural classification as areas with a population of less than 3,000 and over a 60 minute drive time to a settlement with a population of 10,000 or more, an uplift of 20% should be applied. Note that, for schemes which impact on journeys across different area types, the uplift should be applied only to business journeys which originate or terminate in very remote rural areas. Due to limited evidence for the scale of this impact (data is only available for fuel costs, rather than all business costs), the 20% uplift should only be applied as a sensitivity.

9.3.4 Wider benefits arising from improved labour supply

The DfT's work identifies three labour market effects which could have consequences for GDP and which may contribute to welfare benefits through the tax take:

  • WB4a: More people choosing to work as a result of commuting time savings (because one of the costs of working - commuting costs - has fallen)
  • WB4b: some people choosing to work longer hours (because they spend less time commuting)
  • WB4c: relocation of jobs to higher-productive areas (because better transport makes the area more attractive to firms and workers).

The data requirements for WB4 are extensive and further guidance on the application within Scotland will be forthcoming.

9.3.5 Calculation of Wider Economic Benefits

This section details the current position regarding the calculation of Wider Economic benefits (WEBs) within the STAG Appraisal. Details on the presentation of results are given in 9.3.6 but it should be remembered at all times that the current position is that WEBs should be treated as a sensitivity to standard TEE analysis.

9.3.5.1 Agglomeration Benefits - Zonal Method

The methodology proposed (DfT, WebTAG 3.5.14)is based on the observed correlation between density of employment and productivity.

Mathematical Equation

where:

WB1 are the agglomeration benefits of the option (the 'do-something' situation (S)) compared with the do-minimum situation (M), to be calculated; i is a zone for which agglomeration benefits are being calculated - all of the modelled zones are included in the summation; diS, diM are the effective densities of zone i in the do-something situation S and do-minimum situation M respectively, calculated as shown below; diB is the effective density of zone i in the base year (all other values are for the forecast year), likewise calculated using the formula shown below; e is the elasticity of productivity with respect to effective density (Graham D.J, (2005)"Wider Economic Benfits of Transport Improvements); h is GDP per worker in i (see 9.3.5.1 below); and EiS is employment (in the do-something case).

Effective density is a measure of the accessibility of zone i to jobs in all zones. The formula for effective density, of zone i, in situation X (X is base, Do-minimum or Do-Something) is given by:

Mathematical Equation

where EjX is the employment in zone j and gijX is the generalised cost of travelling between zone i and j in situation X. This notion of generalised cost is given by a weighted average over:

  • Passenger travel (commuter and in-work purposes) and goods movement;
  • Traveller modes or goods vehicle types;
  • Car-ownership levels, for passengers; and
  • Times of day, routes and public transport sub-modes.

The weights used in these steps are the numbers of trips (persons or goods vehicles) by mode and purpose in the base case. These weights are based on the numbers of trips between the pair of zones considered in each calculation.

A detailed transport model, such as Transport Model for Scotland (TMfS), can be used to produce a value of agglomeration benefits using the methodology outlined above.

9.3.5.2 Agglomeration Benefits - APARC Method

Using a combination of the Transport Model for Scotland (TMfS) and its land-use component - Transport Economic Land-use Model of Scotland (TELMoS), it is possible to implement the methodology discussed above in Scotland. The level of disaggregation is to each TMfS zone. This is fairly time consuming and requires, at the very least, the use of TMfS.

An alternative, simpler approach is outlined here - the Agglomeration Productivity Aggregate Response Calculator. It should be noted that this approach does not significantly differ theoretically from that discussed above, but is simply an alternative and less resource intensive application. In practice either approach may be used.

The basic principle of the approach is to define a single zone for the purposes of the calculation.

Applying this assumption means that equations 1 and 2 become:

Mathematical Equation

Where superscripts S and M indicate the do-something and do-minimum cases respectively. The key term is g. This represents, under the single zone assumption, a measure of the generalised cost of travelling in the defined zone. It is helpful to rewrite equation 3 as:

Mathematical Equation

and thus, the terms Mathematical Equationand Mathematical Equationrepresent the ratio of the generalised cost of travel in the base year versus the do-something and do-minimum respectively. This is useful as it means that the precise form of generalised cost is not important - what is important is the proportional change of both the do-minimum and do-something over the baseline. This method has the advantage in that the modelling resource requirements are kept to a minimum - any transport model should, in theory, be able to generate a change in total generalised cost.

It is worth noting that gijX as originally defined is a distance based measure - two zones are clearly a physical distance apart as the crow flies although new infrastructure may mean the distance that needs to be traveled may change. The generalised cost measure in the aggregate case is not distance based in the same way.

The first data requirement is the elasticity parameter, e. The current best estimate of this value is 0.041.

Values are also required for h, the level of GDP per worker in the zone. In order to avoid double counting, this value is kept constant between the do-minimum and do-something scenarios.

It is also suggested that total employment is assumed to be constant between the do-minimum and do-something.

Standard assumptions should be applied in terms of GDP and employment growth from the base to the forecast year or years and onward. For consistency with current appraisal techniques, all values are expressed in 2010 prices and discounted over 60 years from scheme opening using standard Green Book values.

These parameters are fixed and suggested values are given in Table 9.1 below for base years between 2002 and 2006. Note that when TMfS is used to calculate agglomeration benefits, it calculates the generalised cost of travel for Scotland as a whole, and therefore national employment and GVA per worker figures should be used. These are also given in Table 9.1. Practitioners should note that the 2% GVA growth figure will be adjusted over time in line with the Government Economic Strategy.

Table 9.1 - Agglomeration Productivity Aggregate Response - Fixed data

Α parameter

1

Elasticity parameter

0.041

2%

0.2%

GVA growth (per annum)

Employment growth (per annum)

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

Employment (000's)

2341

2390

2402

2411

2405

GVA per worker (2002 prices) £

31,653

31,925

32,556

33,389

33,680

The method of arriving at a measure of total generalised cost (GC) for each case is as follows:

1. For each mode/time of day a measure of GC per km traveled is calculated.

2. The total measure of GC is calculated, for each case, by multiplying the GC/km figure for each mode and time of day by the appropriate level of vehicle km in the Base.

It should be noted that there may be variations in the amount of information provided into the above calculation. If this is the case then the basic principle outlined should be followed.

This is consistent with the full methodology and captures the fact that agglomeration is dependant on the impact of changes in the transport system compared with the base. It is worth noting that congestion effects, etc., are captured in the case specific GC figures.

Equation 4 should be used to calculate the extent of agglomeration benefits in each of the forecast years. Values should be discounted back to 2010 for consistency with standard appraisal. If a single forecast year is available, then the agglomeration impact should be held constant in subsequent years. If two forecast years are available, linear interpolation should be used to calculate interim values and the agglomeration benefits should be held constant after the second forecast year.

A spreadsheet is available that can perform the calculation. See Section 17.5.

9.3.5.3 Competition Impacts

The existence of imperfect competition in markets means that prices are higher than production costs (in the economic sense, including a return to capital). As such, business time savings captured in standard Cost Benefit Analysis will underestimate the total benefits to these industries. Data on price-cost margins suggests that a 10% uplift should be added to the value of business time to account for this difference.

This component of wider economic benefits is straightforward to calculate. Standard Transport Economic Efficiency tables should, by default, report the value of business time savings. To calculate the impact of increased output in imperfectly competitive markets, then 10% of this value should be calculated (Laird, J (2009) "Wider Economic Impacts in Remote Areas").

9.3.6 Reporting of Wider Economic Benefits

The results from the Wider Economic Benefits calculations should be presented as an additional sensitivity to the TEE results. The current position of Transport Scotland is that WEBs should not be included in the standard calculation of an NPV and BCR as detailed above. However, a second NPV, termed NPVWEB, and BCR, termed BCRWEB, that sum the standard TEE and WEB results may be presented.

It is important to note that this must, at this stage, be clearly labelled as a sensitivity and the standard TEE results should remain the core reported figure. It is anticipated that this position may change in the future but remains guidance at present. If only a single figure is reported it should remain as the standard value.

The primary driver for this distinction is the difficulties associated with Monitoring and Evaluating the outturn of WEBs. The view is that a stronger focus on WEBs at this stage would undermine the monitoring and evaluation of schemes put forward under STAG.

A suggested approach is shown below:

NPV

BCR

Agglomeration Impacts WB1

From equation 5

Imperfect competition impacts WB3

10% of business time savings

Total Wider Economic benefits

Sum of WB1 +WB3

Adjusted NPV (NPV web)

Adjusted BCR (BCR web)

Transport Scotland recognises that the calculation of agglomeration benefits is an emerging science, and that innovative methodologies are frequently applied. Whichever methodology is employed, practitioners should ensure that their results are reported in a transparent manner. Supporting technical information should be provided, either as part of the Economy AST or as a separate technical annex. Examples of technical data that practitioners may wish to supply are changes in generalised cost, income per worker, and agglomeration elasticities for key zones; however the choice of data deemed most appropriate to support the calculations is left up to the judgement of individual practitioners.

9.4 Economic Activity and Location Impacts (EALI)

The Economic Activity and Location Impact (EALI) analysis provides an assessment of the impact of transport investment or policy measures on the economy, measured in terms of income (GDP or GVA) and/or employment. The EALI analysis assesses the distribution of the national impacts captured through the TEE and WEB, identifying the impacts on different areas. The EALI does not generally identify additional economic impacts that could be added to the TEE or WEB results. However, where market failures exist, the EALI analysis may capture the economic impacts that the TEE analysis may not have fully assessed.

The Scottish Government has Scotland-wide interests and responsibilities and is therefore interested in economic impacts at both the national and local level. The impacts of transport projects are generally highly pervasive and not limited to particular areas. Accordingly, in looking at impacts on the economy it is necessary to assess these at both the Scotland and the regional or sub-regional level.

It will be noted that there has been a change in emphasis from the previous system of EALI with the introduction of the Wider Economic Benefits (WEB) analysis. With the introduction of WEB, the approximation of the total economic impact of an option is more fully captured than with TEE alone. Additionally, the employment effects of an option are captured by the WB4 analysis. As such, there is potentially slightly less focus on the EALI section than may have been the case before the inclusion of WEB.

This issue is currently under review; however, the view of Transport Scotland is that EALI analysis remains important as a tool for analysing the distributional impacts of transport, but that the resources committed to it may be reduced with the incorporation of WEBs.

Net impacts at the Scotland level are likely to be important mainly in larger options that may have some impacts on the level, location or distribution of economic activity, or where there are "threshold" changes in accessibility (generalised cost) that will give rise to changes such as access to labour or to markets. However, the overall net impact is derived from a number of different gross impacts, some of which may be positive and others negative. As a result, even quite small options will have EALIs which are positive for specific areas or for particular groups, and negative for others.

Economic Activity and Location Impact analysis will only be necessary if it has been identified as important or significant within the Part 1 Appraisal. If so, practitioners should seek to identify and qualify impacts at the national and local level. As a practical approach to identifying and quantifying EALIs (at least in orders of magnitude), it is necessary to consider the nature and scale of these on a case by case basis. This is particularly relevant to small projects. The level of depth required in the analysis should be proportional to the size of the option or policy being appraised. However, any decision to omit an EALI analysis must be clearly justified.

9.4.1 Presentation of EALIs

This section provides guidance on the appropriate presentation of EALIs.

9.4.1.1 Gross and Net Impacts

The net impact of a transport option on the Scottish Economy is captured by the TEE and WEB analysis. In STAG, EALIs are reported in two ways, both of which are of interest to decision makers:

  • As a net impact at the Scotland level; and
  • In terms of its gross components, which will distinguish impacts on particular areas and/or on particular groups in society.

Given the advent of WEB, in practice, the primary interest in EALI analysis will therefore be more on local and distributional impacts, where analysis of gross rather than net changes must be considered. This is because even small options have the potential to give rise to changes in economic activity which will benefit some areas or groups while disadvantaging others. For example, replacing parking spaces with bus lanes may have an adverse effect on retail businesses on bus routes, but in general this would lead to a redistribution of retailing activity to nearby areas. By implication, net economic impacts may be negligible at the local level and certainly at the national level. Nevertheless, the gross impacts are important, particularly in terms of determining the likely public acceptability of the option.

Therefore, at the stage of developing an option, decision makers should consider the potential beneficiaries and losers from an option, and the scale of both positive and negative impacts. The EALI approach will provide a structure for identifying such distributional impacts, even though at the Scotland level the net result is likely to be zero.

For most options seeking funding from the Scottish Government the important appraisal output to be considered by the Scottish Government will be the level of net economic benefits as captured by TEE and WEB at the Scotland level and detailed within EALI analysis. This is because the Scottish Government has to assess the use of Scottish resources at the level of Scotland as a whole. However, there are exceptions. These include instances where options affect people/social groups who are the subject of other Scottish Government (or UK Government) policies, such as those suffering from social exclusion and people in remote rural areas.

The EALI appraisal process therefore enables the consideration of aspects of appraisal, such as how economic activity benefits (costs) are distributed. In cases where socially excluded groups or regeneration areas are likely to be affected by an option, the minimum requirement is for the distributional impacts to be included.

9.4.1.2 EALIs and Appraisal Summary Tables (AST)

As described in Section 5, EALIs will be scoped qualitatively in the Part 1 AST in order to establish whether there is a need to undertake a detailed Part 2 Appraisal. The depth of analysis should be proportional and a detailed Part 2 Appraisal of EALIs is unlikely to be required for small options, except where economic impacts are their principal or sole justification, or where the scoping exercise indicates that there are significant positive or negative impacts on particular areas or groups. This is especially important where areas or groups are targeted by other policies such as those designed to tackle social exclusion or regeneration.

9.4.1.3 Inclusion of EALIs in the Appraisal

The results of detailed investigation should be reported in the Part 2 Appraisal and summarised in the Part 2 AST. If the detailed appraisal demonstrates that there are no gross EALIs, this should be stated in Part 2 and the relevant sections of the Part 2 AST need not be completed.

9.4.2 EALIs as the Rationale for a Transport Project

In developing the case for a transport project, it is necessary to consider the extent to which that case rests on economic development or regeneration impacts, rather than on direct transport impacts. For example, where a project is proposed because it will effectively address problems of congestion without expectations of other collateral economic activity impacts (such as attracting local employment by opening up land for industrial and commercial development), then the option appraisal would be conducted against transport objectives.

However, where tackling congestion is seen as essential to the attraction of further economic development, for example in areas experiencing rapid economic growth, then the objectives of that option are in reality economic development rather than transport - transport is a means to economic ends in such a case.

Where the objectives of an option are solely or substantially concerned with economic development or regeneration, the reasons for preferring a transport option rather than other economic development measures needs to be clearly articulated. In keeping with guidance on setting objectives and sifting options, it will be necessary to demonstrate that other economic development measures, as well as transport measures, have been properly considered. This should include consideration of potential synergies between the various measures being appraised.

Where there is a development or regeneration agenda for a particular area, it is likely that in most instances the transport investment will be only one component of a strategy. In this case alternative transport inputs should be tested against total (economic development/regeneration) outcomes.

It is important to make the distinction between projects which facilitate regeneration through transport outcomes and projects that facilitate regeneration as a secondary impact. By way of example, it is quite possible that a new rail link may encourage regeneration from a transport perspective. On the other hand, the upgrading of a transport facility which includes the addition of office or retail space is defined as contributing to regeneration via secondary impacts (although there may be direct transport impacts as well).

It is accepted that these secondary impacts may well be considered important. However, as the STAG Appraisal is concerned primarily with the transport impacts of options, these secondary impacts must be considered separately from the direct transport impacts and should not be presented together with the transport related impacts.

In all cases, but especially where EALIs are central to the case for the option, it is necessary to be able to demonstrate how the economic development or regeneration outcomes can be attributed to the transport option. This should include a discussion of the reasons why the market will not address the economic development or regeneration objectives.

9.4.3 The Basis of Analysis of EALIs

9.4.3.1 Links between EALIs and a Transport Option

In order to identify and assess the scale of any potential EALIs, it is necessary to develop an understanding of how the transport option will generate impacts in terms of GDP (or GVA) and employment. This can be thought of as developing a credible chain of cause and effect, linking the transport option (inputs) to its final economic outcomes, namely output and employment impacts.

In order to develop this, it might be useful to consider a series of questions, beginning with the transport impacts:

  • What will the transport option achieve in terms of transport benefits and costs; for simplicity, focussing on benefits such as time savings, improved accessibility, improved journey quality and so on;
  • Who will benefit from these impacts, and who, if anyone, will lose; where are the beneficiaries (and losers) located:
  • It will be useful here to consider the economic roles of those affected - businesses, workers, tourists and so on;
  • If the nature of commuting time savings is likely to have labour market effects;
  • What are the likely responses of the gainers and losers in terms of travel behaviour; and
  • What are the likely responses in terms of economic behaviour.

To use an example, the link from an improved ferry service to an island through to economic activity and location impacts is straightforward to conceptualise, as improved accessibility should make that island more competitive as a leisure destination (for most of the market). This should lead to an increase in visitor numbers and hence expenditure, and this in turn should expand employment and output.

9.4.3.2 Assessing Gross and Net Impacts

As discussed above, in both the scoping (Part 1 AST) and detailed (Part 2 AST) appraisals, it is necessary to consider:

  • How individual (gross) impacts arise;
  • How these affect particular areas and/or groups; and
  • How these combine to give net impacts at "local" and national (Scotland or UK depending on sources of funding) levels.

In undertaking this analysis, it is necessary to consider how the transport option potentially affects economic activity, first at a local level and then at the Scotland level. It is then necessary to undertake research on this at a level commensurate with the size of the transport option and the significance of potential EALIs as part of the case for that option. Guidance on practical approaches is given below in the section on the Part 2 AST and in the section on further technical guidance.

First, however, it may be useful to illustrate the point regarding gross and net impacts using the above example of a ferry service. Tourist visitors to that island who would come even without the improved service gain through improved accessibility, but this may have little overall impact for the island as a whole, but time savings might translate into re-distributing visits to more remote parts of the island.

In addition, improved access could also lead to more people travelling to that island and hence more tourist bed-nights, which generate both an output and employment impact at the level of that particular island. Here there could be both positive and negative gross impacts; there could for example be a negative impact from loss of expenditure by tourists who decide not to come if the island is perceived to have become "crowded", but a larger positive impact arising through a larger increase in new visitors who would not have come had the ferry not been improved.

However, where the extra travellers would have come to Scotland regardless of the improved ferry service, the impact of the service for these visitors is to re-distribute their travel and associated expenditure to the island with the improved ferry service at the expense of other areas.

Thus the impact at the island level may be positive, and within the island there may also be redistribution benefits, but at the Scotland level the net impact is likely to be zero, as the additional expenditure on the island will almost certainly be at the expense of places elsewhere in Scotland. If a case were made for a positive (or negative) net impact, convincing evidence would be required to justify such a case.

9.4.4 Part 2 AST - Identification and Quantification

In cases where the Part 1 scoping has identified EALIs as potentially important or significant, in Part 2 it will be necessary to identify and quantify the impacts. As a practical approach to identifying and quantifying EALIs (at least in orders of magnitude), it is necessary to consider the nature and scale of these impacts on a case by case basis. Such an approach was recommended by SACTRA for all but the largest options, for which a more comprehensive approach involving formal modelling might be more appropriate.

9.4.4.1 Developing a Case by Case Approach

A case by case approach must be tailored specifically to the transport option under consideration and to the appropriate area or spatial level. This forms a partial analysis, which involves a detailed segmentation of the economic actors in the spatial areas relevant to the appraisal of the option. The following sets out a feasible approach which involves completing two analysis forms (shown here in Tables 9.2 and 9.4). The information used in completing these tables can be transferred directly to the Part 2 AST.

The approach outlined here can be tailored to particular studies and local circumstances, with the degree of quantification appropriate to the size of the study, the scale of the option under consideration and the expected relative significance of EALIs (both positive and negative) in the overall appraisal.

The case specific approach suggested here involves analysis of the potential behavioural responses of different "sectors" of economic activity. Here, the term "sector" has been used to describe different types or areas of economic activity, such as the manufacturing sector. Within each sector are "economic actors" whose decisions affect the economic performance of an area or region. Economic actors include businesses both in an area and outside it, land and property developers, and individuals in their roles as residents, workers, shoppers, visitors and tourists.

The following is a possible segmentation, adopted in Table 9.2, which could be used:

  • Existing manufacturing and process industries, which produce physical products: this may usefully be segmented by sector/industry, and/or by size;
  • Service businesses, which may be sub-segmented into those serving the local area and those which export services outwith that area; and/or by whether a physical product is produced;
  • Mobile/inward/foreign direct investment, which may be capable of being attracted to the area;
  • Tourists, who may be considered as a specific market served primarily by local service industries;
  • Day visitors including shoppers, also a specific service sector market; and
  • Working residents, who may migrate from or to the area and who may have jobs in or outwith the area.

The above is suggested as a general starting point for segmentation of economic activity into sectors; however, not all will be relevant or important in some areas, while in other areas it might be necessary to sub-segment sectors, for example where there are many different types of manufacturing industries where different industry responses to a transport option might be expected.

Once a usable segmentation has been selected, this approach involves investigating how the economic actors relevant to each sector might be affected by, and respond to, the changes in costs or accessibility brought about by the transport option under analysis. As outlined below, in most instances much of the required analysis will be based on survey evidence and accessibility analysis.

For example, in considering the business sectors, including the tourism industry and retailing, a combination of data gathering and structured interviews could be used in order to establish:

  • Current performance, including size, recent growth, profitability/margins;
  • Future objectives and aspirations - products, size, markets, production locations;
  • Current and future/expected constraints, to include physical resources, human resources, management and capital;
  • Output/product market conditions/competitiveness; location and size of main competitors;
  • The significance of transport and accessibility to the business; and
  • The role of changes in transport costs and journey time reliability in overcoming constraints and achieving future objectives and aspirations.

This process could also be advised by other data gathering, analysis and interviews, including suppliers and professional advisers, and in particular the property and recruitment sectors. The latter are important with regard to gathering information and opinion on impacts relating to land-use and labour market factors respectively.

The EALI assessment table includes these, albeit in a simpler form, but a fuller treatment of these can be found in SACTRA (paragraph 10.158 et seq.). Here the basis of the analysis is to assess how a transport option will impact upon each sector of the spatial economy under consideration. Such impacts will arise through factors such as:

  • Market and competitiveness changes, such as costs of delivery or increased reliability of logistics systems and lower costs of access to supplies;
  • Labour market impacts through access to a larger pool of labour, which might have efficiency benefits;
  • Land and property impacts arising through access to land for business development and expansion or the attraction of mobile investment; and
  • The distribution of the Agglomeration impacts from WB1.

In order to adopt a systematic approach to the identification and quantification of impacts, each case should be segmented to identify the principal sectors which act as the sources or drivers of economic performance at the appropriate spatial level. Then for each sector, the potential role of the option in enhancing its economic performance needs to be considered. Generally, this will require an understanding of the potential responses of the economic actors within each sector to the transport option. This could usefully be informed by the methodology set out in Section 11 for Accessibility and Social Inclusion impacts. Change in accessibility for each people group and employment sectors indicates the positive and negative pressures and assists in developing understanding of the links between causes and effects.

The suggested way of bringing together information is to use the Summary Assessment Table, shown as Table 9.2. For most options, this should be derived from completion of individual sector tables. It should be noted that the activity sectors shown in Table 9.2 are indicative and may be changed depending on the option and its likely impacts. In some instances, sectors might be omitted while some sectors might require further segmentation to permit the necessary level of analysis. An example of a completed summary table is shown in Table 9.3.

Table 9.2: Potential EALIs - Summary Assessment Table

Year of Assessment

Summary of Impacts

(year):

Local

National

Sector

Gains / Gainers

Losses / Losers

Gains / Gainers

Losses / Losers

Manufacturing and Processing

Locally Traded Services

Externally Traded Services

Inward/Mobile Investment

Tourism

Day Trips/Shoppers

Residents

Sector Interactions/

Synergies

Total Gross Impacts

Net Impact

Overall Impacts
Local: National:

Summary of Distributional Impacts
Local: National:

Table 9.3: Completed Example of Potential EALIs - Summary Assessment Table

Year of Assessment

Summary of Impacts

(year): 2006

Local

National

Sector

Gains / Gainers

Losses / Losers

Gains / Gainers

Losses / Losers

Manufacturing and

Processing

1200-1300 jobs

£70-90m in GDP

None

as local

Very limited - loss estimated up to 100 jobs

Locally Traded Services

Zero

Zero

Zero

Zero

Externally Traded Services

Zero

Zero

Zero

Zero

Inward/Mobile Investment

500-1000 jobs

£40-80m GDP

Zero

Zero

Zero

Tourism

Zero

Zero

Zero

Zero

Day Trips/Shoppers

Zero

Zero

Zero

Zero

Residents

500-1000

additional residents

Zero

Zero

Zero

Sector Interactions/

Synergies

200-500 jobs

£15-40m

Zero

100-200 jobs

£10-20m GDP

Zero

Total Gross Impacts

1900-2800 jobs

£125-210m

GDP

Zero

1300-1500 jobs

£80-110m GDP

loss of 100 jobs, up to £10m GDP

Net Impact

Overall Impacts Local: 1900-2800 jobs; £125-210m GDP National:

1200-1400 jobs; £70-100m GDP

Summary of Distributional Impacts Local: potential for benefits in regeneration areas affected by the option, and also at peripheries of TTWA National: minimal losses in competitor companies, likely to be short term as external markets expanding

 

Table 9.4 should be completed to set out those impacts which have been examined in detail and quantified. An example of a completed sector table is shown in Table 9.5.

This two step approach is suggested because a review of the qualitative version should help practitioners in identifying which impacts are most important (in gross terms) and hence to determine where to focus efforts to derive quantitative estimates of impacts.

Taking the individual sectors first, for each sector of activity, the assessment (shown in Table 9.4 and completed as an example in Table 9.5) should:

  • First, provide an analysis of current market conditions and constraints relating to each individual sector: these can be analysed under the headings of land/physical resources, labour/human resources and product market impacts, which can be analysed at local and national levels. In certain cases it might also be necessary to include access to natural and /or manufactured resources and supplies;
  • Second, provide (and justify) an assessment of how the transport intervention is expected to contribute towards enhanced performance in each sector: this must address inter and intra regional/area impacts;
  • Third, consider how sectors might interact: for example, where there are links between sectors or where growth of one activity might feed through to impacts in other sectors, the assessment should at least describe potential interactions; and
  • Fourth, set out an overview of the gross output (GDP or GVA) and/or employment impacts at the appropriate local and national spatial levels.

Once this analysis has been completed for each identified sector or driver, the results should be summarised using Table 9.1; the completed example shown as Table 9.2 suggests how these findings might be summarised and presented.

Table 9.4: Sector Table: Qualitative/Quantitative Analysis of First Round Impacts (Manufacturing and Processing)

Sector

Manufacturing and Processing

Sources / Types of Impact

Qualitative

Quantitative

Market / Competitiveness Context

Labour Market Impacts

Land / Property Impacts

Product

Market

Impacts

Local

National

Overall Impacts

Local

Gainers

Local Losers

National Gainers

National Losers

Table 9.5: Completed Example of Qualitative/Quantitative Analysis of First Round Impacts (Manufacturing and Processing)

Sector

Manufacturing and Processing

Sources / Types of Impact

Qualitative

Quantitative

Market /Competitiveness Context

High % of firms & jobs in highly competitive markets where changes in transport costs will have potential impacts. Principal markets in England and Europe: local accessibility poor & journey times very unreliable, impacts on need for non-optimal working times & use of vehicles / drivers

Total of 3,500 manufacturing jobs in local TTWAs, 2,500 - 2,700 in volume / low margin sectors suffering from local transport related constraints

Labour Market Impacts

Labour shortages in skilled & semi-skilled trades currently constraining output in 60 - 70% of firms accounting for around 80% of total employment. Labour pool area constrained because of local accessibility / costs / travel times. Potential to tap under/unemployed labour in wider TTWA

Potential to recruit / train / employ 200 - 300 additional workers in short - medium term

Land / Property Impacts

Half of all major firms seeking additional land, 3 have alternative locations in Scotland, 4 considering non Scotland expansions. Land severely constrained by access, planning and cost factors

Potential loss of around 1,000 jobs which could be retained if land can be made available locally

Product Market Impacts

Local

None expected; non Scottish firms have very limited market presence & surge of imports considered very unlikely: no displacement impact expected.

Zero

National

Principal markets are external; potential for expansion of sales through lower cost access to markets and access to labour which currently limits output and adds to costs. Very high % of Scottish output within TWWAs examined.

Expansion of output and employment: est'd GDP annual value of £20m, (excluding any multiplier effects); 200-300 jobs in short-medium term

Overall Impacts

Local Gainers

Two principal sources of impact: output & employment impacts through combined labour & product market impacts substantial output & employment benefits through retention of existing manufacturing activity which otherwise would relocate due to limited access and land for expansion Gainers are those with skills or semi skilled living in wider TTWA plus some jobs to people in regeneration areas - requires job access and training schemes by LEC

Output impacts estimated GDP annual value of £20m, excluding multiplier effects Plus up to 1000 jobs retained, accounting for estimated £50 - £70 million

Local

Losers

No local losers identified

National Gainers

As above, plus possible multiplier impacts within wider TTWA where there are unemployed resources

As above

National Losers

Limited expected losers as almost all production concentrated in the group of TTWAs examined

Very limited potential displacement within Scotland

9.4.5 Further Technical Guidance

For further information in this area please consult the report by SACTRA, Transport and the Economy.

9.4.5.1 Applying a Sectoral Approach

Existing Industries and Activities

Market conditions set the context for economic activity impacts. It is therefore important to consider the competitive conditions in each sector, and how these will be affected by the transport option. Where competition is imperfect, for example in industries in which there are few players and barriers to new competition, a transport option might promote greater competitiveness leading to more efficient production and/or better use of human and/or physical resources.

Such changes will generally enable an increase in output and employment: however, as noted by SACTRA (in Transport and the Economy), competitiveness impacts are a potential consequence where inter-regional links are improved. For example, businesses in a formerly remote region might benefit if the transport option reduces delivery costs into external markets; however the same option also opens up the markets in that region which were previously protected from external competition by transport costs. This illustrates why it is important to look at gross impacts, as this enables this so-called "two way street" effect to be considered.

Competitiveness impacts may also occur through factor markets, for example expanding the labour market catchment area and making it easier and quicker for companies to recruit personnel, or by expanding the supply of land suitable for industrial and commercial activities.

In addition to competitiveness based impacts, consideration should be given to other potential market failures.

Inward Investment

The ability to attract mobile or inward investment is frequently put forward as a reason for a transport option, generally in relation to land-use or access to rail, air or port facilities. It is not enough simply to assert that such investment will arise, however, and evidence needs to be obtained to show that there is demand from potential investors which cannot be met in some other way or in some other location. As with other economic actors, this will generally involve use of survey information.

In looking at this issue, information could be gathered from investors who did locate in the appropriate spatial area and with others who considered the area but chose to locate elsewhere. This should include information/opinion on why an area was selected/not selected; as far as possible, survey techniques should be used which elicit information on the relative importance of transport factors. In practice, it may be necessary to rely to a large degree on agencies involved in inward investment.

Population Change and Economic Performance

Gain or loss of working residents may be an important driver of local income performance, and the attraction of people with skills can help an area to attract new investment. The attraction of more people with jobs either in or outwith the in-scope area will also add to local spending power and the tax base, while loss of people will reduce income if not replaced. Inter-area and intra-area transport accessibility will play a role in the attraction of people and the location of place of residence in relation to place of work, as will factors such as housing availability and costs, location of services such as schools and other factors which affect overall quality of life.

In examining this issue, evidence may be gathered through surveys of individuals in cases where this is seen to be an important benefit from the option under consideration. In other instances, information from property agents may be adequate to show that transport infrastructure plays a role in the ability of an area to attract/retain residents. Additional information on this sector could involve discussions with the development industry, property agents and the public sector, the latter as planning authority and provider of basic infrastructure.

It should be noted that attracting residents who would otherwise locate elsewhere involves displacement, and should be treated as a positive impact only where increasing resident numbers or strengthening the social mix of the population is a policy objective, as may be the case in regeneration areas.

While partial and to a degree qualitative, this approach can be used to consider both future economic and other trends in an area, and also future developments such as housing. The role of the transport option in inducing or enabling such development can be considered, but this will also help to identify developments which are not induced by the transport option but which may give rise to additional demand on the transport network.

9.4.5.2 Selection of the Appropriate Spatial Level for Assessment

In all cases, the impacts need to be reported at a national level, but in presenting findings, it will generally be necessary to indicate how different areas or regions are affected. Where areas affected include locations with some form of regeneration designation, or where the justification for an option depends upon impacts affecting a particular area, the impacts on such areas need to be distinguished as specific distributional impacts.

In order to look first at the immediate and direct consequences emanating from the transport option, it may be useful to conceptualise impacts as intra-area and then inter-area. It is necessary to consider "two way street" effects, whereby transport links between regions open up scope for new economic interactions. An example of this is where a new road links two regions; firms in region A are then better able to compete within region B, but similarly firms in region B are better able to compete in region A's market. The net impact may be lower prices and more production at the Scotland level, but more detailed analysis would be needed to assess the impacts on individual regions.

While impacts need to be reported at the Scotland and appropriate local/regional levels, consideration must be given to how best to conduct the appraisal and in particular the data gathering required. In deciding how to conduct research to assess EALIs, it will generally be useful to consider:

  • The direct or immediate EALIs which will arise within the area directly affected by the transport option; and
  • The spatially wider EALIs, which will arise as these direct effects work through to the rest of the economy.

It is likely that, where a transport option is relatively small and can be expected to have only localised transport impacts, a high proportion of both transport and economic impacts will accrue within a distinct travel to work area. Impacts outside that area are likely to be dispersed and difficult to assess efficiently. In such instances it will generally be sensible to focus on the local impacts.

9.4.5.3 Place and People Impacts

A further factor to be examined in considering the spatial level(s) for the appraisal is the people dimension. While it is convenient to think in terms of spatial areas, especially where there are regeneration areas, policies are ultimately targeted at people rather than places. Policies which address place issues such as the visual environment do so in order to bring about some ultimate benefit for the people living in or experiencing that environment.

Therefore while it is helpful to begin by looking at areas, the ultimate consideration is the extent to which people or social groups who are targeted by Government policies on social inclusion will in reality be the beneficiaries. For example, where a new tram option stimulates developer interest in an area and helps to open up land for development in or close to a regeneration area, the associated jobs might be claimed as a benefit because of their location in or close to a regeneration area.

However, if the jobs are all for graduates then the people living in the regeneration area are very unlikely to benefit from these jobs. Accordingly, in claiming a gross or distributional employment impact, care must be taken to ensure that there is a sound case. This should be based not only on place/location arguments but also on the argument that the people or social groups targeted by regeneration policies are actually likely to benefit from the jobs arising from the transport project.

9.4.5.4 Multiplier Impacts

Where there is spare capacity in the economy, there may be subsequent multiplier impacts arising through the purchasing of inputs by businesses and by the spending of wages and salaries. Such effects will be highly pervasive beyond local impacts, and the smaller the area under consideration, the greater the likelihood that the income will "leak" out of the area. Given the economic context of the option, consideration should be given to whether such effects are likely.

For example, in areas where there are skill or labour shortages, it is difficult to argue that there is spare capacity in the economy and hence to include local multipliers in the appraisal. However, there may be multiplier impacts at the Scotland level where businesses and residents in the local fully employed area purchase goods and services from areas with spare capacity.

In contrast, in regeneration areas multiplier impacts are more likely, provided income is spent within the area, as such areas are characterised by the availability of spare labour capacity.

In all instances where a multiplier impact is considered, account needs to be taken of where incomes are generated and where they are spent. If income is earned by residents of a regeneration area but is largely spent outside that area, it will not be appropriate to apply local level multipliers to all of the identified increase in local income. Where the regeneration area is small, the level of leakage is likely to be very high, and in such cases multiplier effects may be minimal.

Where it is proposed to include multipliers in the estimates of EALIs additional advice on this topic can be obtained from the Scottish Government. Useful advice on values for regeneration areas will be found in A Framework for the Evaluation of Regeneration Projects and Programmes (HM Treasury, January 1995).

9.4.5.5 Defining Areas - The Role of Travel to Work Areas

In cases where the immediate impacts are expected to be relatively localised, the travel to work areas within which the transport impacts occur may realistically be the areas within which to commit effort in assessing the immediate EALIs arising from that transport option. This would be appropriate where, for example, much of the impact arises from changes in accessibility within local labour markets.

However, there may be circumstances where there will be further impacts outside the focus area which need to be considered, for example where increased labour productivity within that area might result in other impacts elsewhere in the economy.

For larger options, a number of travel to work areas may be involved, and for such options the appropriate spatial level for considering labour market impacts may be a whole sub-region such as central Scotland. Larger transport projects are also more likely to affect product markets or sectors such as tourism or the attraction of mobile investment, and accordingly the economic impacts will fall over a very wide area and need to be considered at a regional or national level.

9.4.5.6 The Use of Gross Impacts

Economic development arguments for investment are frequently made on a distributional basis, typically in order to benefit a particular area or social group. Areas include those which are the focus of other economic policy initiatives, such as remote rural areas, urban housing estates and under-performing/regeneration areas; social groups include the long-term and young unemployed and single parents, many of whom have multiple problems of accessibility to jobs and training.

While a transport investment may have EALIs for a particular area and/or social group, for example by significantly enhancing access to jobs or opening up land which is otherwise not available, it is highly unlikely that these impacts will be net benefits at the national level when measured purely in terms of the value of national output. This is because measures such as improving jobs access will generally redistribute employment opportunities without expanding labour demand through an associated impact on output by employing industries. This results in offsetting displacement elsewhere, while not increasing the total number of jobs available. How this is treated will, however, depend upon the areas affected.

In particular, where impacts accrue to areas which receive special treatment or additional resources in order to achieve regeneration objectives, it might reasonably be argued that these benefits should not be totally "netted out" at the national level. Therefore a gain of 100 jobs to residents of a "regeneration area" might be presented as a positive employment distribution benefit of up to 100 jobs, even if it results in a displacement effect of 100 jobs in a non-regeneration area and no gain in output. In other words, some or all of the displacement might arguably be discounted in certain circumstances; however, outside such areas, displacement impacts need to be fully netted out.

There may, of course, be instances where accessibility improvements result in gains in output. For example, such impacts could arise where labour markets are so constrained by poor accessibility that there is an inability to achieve a match between skills on offer in some areas and skills required in others. In such circumstances, better accessibility should lead to more output through productivity effects of better skill matches and shorter periods to fill skilled vacancies. Similarly, where improved accessibility to training expands the availability of labour skills which are in short supply, it is possible that output will increase as a consequence of better accessibility.

However, where the impact of accessibility change falls on people who have no, or inappropriate, skills and who are not in short supply, then where such people gain jobs because of accessibility improvements, the impacts are likely to be distributional. This is because in a situation where this category of labour is in excess supply, others would have been employed had the accessibility improvements not been made; as a consequence, this will involve displacement. If there are specific regeneration objectives for the area, a change which enables residents of such areas to obtain employment may properly be regarded as a distributional welfare gain and should be noted as such under distributional impacts, provided this gain is not at the expense of residents of other regeneration areas. The earlier footnote provided further guidance on this point.

Similarly, opening up development land in one area will almost always represent activity that would have taken place elsewhere, in which case there will be no additional impact. However, if the area in which development takes place is one designated as a regeneration area, there is a potential distributional gain provided that development clearly enables residents of the regeneration area to secure (additional) employment. Accordingly, it is necessary to make clear the spatial level at which the appraisal is being conducted, and where a sub-national level is used, to make a case for doing so based on factors such as regeneration policy.

It is likely that in practice the core transport analysis will be conducted for an area considered to be in-scope for the effects of the transport improvements such as journey times. This may be a small area or a whole corridor, depending on the nature and scale of the intervention. As discussed above, it will in practice be necessary to decide on the most appropriate spatial area at which to conduct the EALI analysis, and this will involve a judgement regarding how and how far the economic effects of the particular transport changes are transmitted and the practical issue of information gathering.

It is essential to report impacts at both the local and the national level. In reporting EALIs it will be necessary to set out estimates of gross additional (attributable) impacts, both positive and negative, at the appropriate spatial levels, and also to show displacement impacts also at the appropriate spatial levels.

In practice, in reporting impacts at the Scotland level, an appraisal where there are no "regeneration" or special policy areas may usefully distinguish:

  • Direct or immediate impacts within the travel to work area(s) affected by the transport option being appraised; and
  • Positive and negative economic impacts outside this area, in order to present a net assessment.

Table 9.6 below might be useful in showing these impacts.

If it is expected that some of the displacement impacts will fall within a "regeneration" area, these should be noted separately within the rest of Scotland impacts, using a supplementary table based on the above. Similarly, where impacts within the immediate travel to work area fall within a "regeneration" area, these should be shown separately within the immediate area impacts.

Table 9.6: Sample Presentation of Spatial Impacts

Area

Employment impact

Immediate travel to work/local area

Employment gains (additional)
employment losses (displacement)

200
140

a
b

Net impact within immediate area

60

a - b

Rest of Scotland (outside above area)

Employment gains (additional)
Employment losses (displacement)

20
55

c
d

Net impact - rest of Scotland

- 35

c -d

Net impact - Scotland

25

= (a-b)
+ (c-d)

9.4.5.7 Measurement Over Time

The economic activity and location impacts of transport projects will be experienced as a future flow of additional GDP/GVA and jobs, and as such it may be necessary to consider impacts over time, rather than just at a particular point in time. The summary table (Table 9.2) provides a column in which the time frame for assessment should be stated, and this should also be used to refer to more detailed supporting information on the assumptions and caveats relating to forecasting or projecting impacts over future years.

In principle, the EALI analysis could be treated in the same manner as TEE benefits, by creating an estimated flow of impacts which is then discounted to a present value at the prevailing discount rate. While this is in principle relatively straightforward in the case of output (although even here there may be issues regarding use of market values, and the need to allow for costs to Government), the treatment of employment is more complex and would require specific guidance. In practice, there are real difficulties forecasting industry level impacts even a few years ahead.

For employment, the familiar measure is a "job" but for appraisal purposes it is necessary to consider what this means over a period of years. The accepted convention is that a job equates to 10 person years of employment, discounted at the prevailing rate. Therefore, where an option generates a stream of person years of employment, these need to be discounted and divided by 10 to give a "job". Further information may be found in the EGRUP guidance, A Framework for the Evaluation of Regeneration Projects and Programmes (HM Treasury January 1995).

9.4.5.8 Full and Temporal Additionality

The term "full additionality" refers to situations where a change in output/employment is the difference between what would happen with and without the transport option. For example, if a road option would enable a site to be developed, the local impact might be stated as, say, 250 jobs, if no other site were available for development if the option did not go ahead.

However, in many cases a transport project will simply enhance what is happening in a local economy, and might therefore simply accelerate the rate of development of sites. This in effect changes the time profile of development when comparing the "with" and "without" option scenarios, and the impact of the project has to be measured as the difference between the stream of impacts with and without the option.

Where GDP/GVA impacts can be measured and valued, this is simply a matter of discounting the "with" and "without" streams to the present day and showing the present value of the difference between these streams. In the case of employment, the principle is the same, namely that the "with" and "without" streams of person years of employment must be discounted to the present day and each divided by 10 to get the "job" impact. The "temporal additionality" impact of the option is the difference between the two "jobs" totals.

In practice, there may be difficulties in projecting output and employment impacts forward, and simplifying assumptions may be required. As a minimum, there should be a brief statement of the expected impacts, expressed as a range and with an indicative time frame, over a 3 to 5 year horizon and with some qualitative indication of potential longer term impacts. For consistency and comparability, these ranges of impacts should be projected ahead to provide time streams of impacts which can then be discounted to present values. Where the impact of the transport option is to increase the rate of growth/development of an area over an expected trend/rate based on the do-nothing or do-minimum (or without option) scenario, the forward projections need to be undertaken at the different estimated "with" and "without option" growth rates. Caveats and assumptions should in all cases be made explicit and justified.

9.4.5.9 Construction and Operations Related Employment

Construction jobs are frequently claimed as a benefit from the implementation of transport (and other) investment options. Similarly, the employment of people to operate transport equipment and maintain the infrastructure is also frequently claimed as a benefit. However, a number of factors affect the validity of such claims.

Construction jobs tend to be temporary, often using outside labour, and are unlikely to contribute to local employment in the longer term. The construction sector, like many other areas, also has a high incidence of skill shortages, and the use of construction labour for one project will in such areas simply displace that labour from other projects, resulting in delays to other work and/or escalation of construction costs. In other areas, where there is spare capacity in the construction sector, it might be reasonable to argue that the employment associated with the implementation of a transport option represents an employment benefit at the local level. This would have more validity if the labour were drawn from regeneration or other policy priority areas.

Similar arguments apply to labour required to operate a new transport option, and here direct displacement of employment arising from, for example, transfer of travellers from one mode to another should also be considered.

In quantifying such employment impacts, the principles set out above regarding temporal additionality should be applied.

9.4.5.10 Land-Use and Development Related Impacts

In practice, for many transport projects the source of economic activity and location impacts is an expected release of constraints on land availability. Where a transport investment does enable land that would otherwise be incapable of development to be developed for productive uses, there is potentially a local economic benefit, where the use of the land gives rise to output and employment impacts.

However, even at a local level the argument that the EALI is additional is valid only where no other site is available which could be developed in a similar manner. Where there is a potential site whose use is ruled out through environmental/planning considerations, the benefit of using the site released by the transport project is in effect related to planning and/or environment objectives rather than economic objectives. However, it is very unlikely that no alternative site would have been available for that development, and therefore the impact at the Scotland level should be noted as zero, unless there is a convincing argument that the development would have gone elsewhere. Similar considerations apply to employment impacts.

It is possible that even where there is no economic (output or employment) impact, because development would take place elsewhere, there may be an environmental gain, where that alternative land has a higher environmental value than that made accessible and developable through the transport intervention. If such a gain were expected, it would be useful to note this in the EALI section, so as to make decision makers aware of how this impact has been assessed. However, as this is an environmental gain, it should be addressed fully in the section on environment.

It should be noted for options requiring SEA, that the SEA Directive's definition of "environment" includes not only the natural environment and the historic environment, but also some human effects such as health and material assets. Therefore within the SEA process, significant effects on material assets should be assessed and presented in the SEA Environmental Report. Material assets include land-use and development-related impacts such as effects on infrastructure, and property.

9.4.6 Additional Guidance for Part 2 AST

9.4.6.1 Reporting EALIs

For consistency in appraisal, consideration must be given to the scale and nature of possible EALIs in all cases. Where no impacts are expected, this must be stated, together with the reasons why this is the case, using the EALI section of the AST.

In all cases therefore, there are three elements in the AST which need to be completed. This section provides some additional guidance in completing these sections.

9.4.6.2 Local and National Economic Impacts

These two sections should be used to summarise output (GDP/GVA) and/or employment impacts at both the local level and the national level, based on the information provided in Table 9.2.

Either GDP or GVA (GDP at basic prices, excluding taxes (less subsidies) on products) can be used to measure output. The Scottish Government uses the GVA measure in its quarterly series. Each is a standard measure of economic activity; GDP impact should be estimated on the basis of expected changes in output arising from the option. Under the heading quantitative information, there should be a brief statement of the expected impacts, expressed as a range and with an indicative time frame, for example over a 3 to 5 year horizon and with some indication of longer term impacts. Depending on the sources of impacts and the scale of the option, GDP impacts should be provided at a detailed level using an appropriate segmentation of economic activity in the in-scope area.

Under the heading qualitative information, the rationale for expecting such changes in output should be provided, and this should include the factors noted above, including in particular changes in competitiveness, labour market impacts and effects on land supply/constraints.

Where there is an expected release of constraints on land availability, such impacts should be indicated clearly. It should be noted that where a transport investment enables land which would otherwise be incapable of development to be developed for productive uses, there is potentially a local economic benefit, where the use of the land gives rise to output and employment impacts. However, it is very unlikely that no alternative site would have been available for that development, and therefore the impact at the Scotland level should be noted as zero, unless there is a convincing argument that the development would have gone elsewhere.

It is possible that even where there is no economic (output or employment) impact, because development would take place elsewhere, there may be an environmental gain, where that alternative land has a higher environmental value than that made accessible and developable through the transport intervention. If such a gain is expected, it should be noted here and quantified, if possible, in the section on environment.

The information used to estimate output changes could also provide the basis for estimation of employment changes, and similar considerations to those set out above also apply to employment impacts. Employment changes can be measured in a variety of ways, but ideally should be measured by estimating numbers in employment at different dates over the life of the option, in order to produce an estimate of person years of employment. This should be provided under the heading quantitative information.

In smaller options, simpler indicators can be used, such as jobs in snapshot years. Changes in employment are of particular interest where the project will benefit people who are unemployed or underemployed, as occurs in regeneration areas, for example. The rationale for expecting changes in employment should be provided under the heading qualitative information.

9.4.6.3 Distributional Impacts

The GDP/employment sections of the AST are intended to present a summary of the appraisal in terms of GDP and employment, and impacts will generally be shown as net impacts. However, there may be cases where a statement of the net impact hides important gross changes, especially where these affect particular areas or social groups.

Practitioners should generally include such gross impacts in their AST and these would be presented in the section on distributional impacts. Depending on the context, it may be helpful to show impacts separately in terms of both "place" (area) impacts and "people" impacts (by social group).

Distributional impacts will be particularly important where an option affects a regeneration area or a particular social group targeted by the Government. In this part of the AST, it is important to indicate any positive or negative distributional impacts arising from an option which affects regeneration areas and/or socially excluded groups. This should include those impacts arising from changes in the spatial characteristics of economic activity.

In such cases it is necessary to indicate where and how a particular "regeneration" area and its residents are affected. This should show gross impacts affecting regeneration and non-regeneration areas. The nature and sources of such impacts should be indicated under the heading qualitative information, while quantitative estimates of gross impacts should be shown under the quantitative information heading.

Even where there is not a designated regeneration area, there may be groups such as the long term unemployed, the elderly and the disabled who could be affected by an option. Impacts upon such groups should be indicated under the qualitative and quantitative headings. Where relevant, these impacts should be cross-referenced to the section dealing with accessibility and social inclusion.

It should be noted for options requiring a SEA, that the SEA Regulations' definition of "environment" includes human effects such as population. As such there is some overlap with the assessment of distributional impacts within the STAG Appraisal. Therefore, within the SEA process, significant effects on population, if relevant to the plan or programme, should be assessed and presented in the SEA Environmental Report.

9.5 Appraisal Parameters

9.5.1 Appraisal Period

The appraisal period used for all transport appraisals will be 60 years. The extension to a 60 year appraisal period was prompted by the reduction to the discount rate in the 2003 version of the HM Treasury Green Book.

For some projects, the project life may be determined from the limited life of its component assets. In these cases, the practitioner should set out the evidence, and select an appropriate end year for the appraisal, subject to a maximum of 60 years. Guidance may be sought from the Scottish Government and/or Transport Scotland on the appropriate appraisal period.

9.5.2 Inflation

When forming base cost estimates for transport options, practitioners should apply realistic assumptions about changes in real costs i.e. above the rate of growth in general prices across the economy. For example, the inflation rates relevant to the delivery of many of the current transport schemes in Scotland (all modes) are currently higher than the general rise in prices across the economy. It is not practical to identify general inflation rates that would apply generally to all transport options so practitioners are advised that any assumptions should be based on the best information on current and forecast inflation from industry sources appropriate to their scheme. These assumptions and the sources of evidence should be clearly stated in the appraisal documentation.

9.5.3 Discounting

Discounting is a technique used to compare costs and benefits that occur in different time periods. It is a separate concept from inflation, and is based on the principle that, generally, society prefers to receive goods and services now rather than later, and to defer costs to future generations. This is known as 'social time preference'. The 'social time preference rate' (STPR) is the rate at which society values the present compared to the future.

9.5.4 Discount Rates

HM Treasury recommends a discount rate of 3.5%, which declines over time (i.e. 3.5% for appraisal years 0 to 30 and 3.0% for years 31 to 75 etc. - refer to Table 6.1 of Green Book). Consequently transport appraisals should adopt the standard rate of 3.5% for the period up to 30 years from the year of appraisal and the lower rate of 3.0% for years 31 to 60. Using these discount rates, £1 would be worth roughly the same value in 60 years as it would have been worth in using the previous rates and 30 year appraisal period.

9.5.5 Base Year for Discounting

The base year that all costs and benefits should be discounted to is currently 2010.

9.5.6 Units of Account

The Treasury Green Book recommends the use of market prices as the basis for appraisal. NATA requires the use of a market price base, arguing that this is consistent with the use of 'willingness to pay', as recommended in Sugden's report Developing a Consistent Cost-Benefit Framework for Multi-Modal Transport.

The market price unit of account expresses prices in market prices. Market price refers to the price paid by consumers for goods and services in the market and therefore includes all indirect taxation (indirect taxation refers to taxation levied on a product and therefore includes excises, duties and VAT). Prices that do not include taxation (e.g. public transport fares) are still perceived by consumers in the market price unit of account.

The factor cost unit of account expresses prices in resource costs. Resource costs are costs that are net of indirect taxation. The prices paid by Government for goods and services are not subject to indirect taxation as any tax that is paid by Government bodies is recovered by Government and thus may be ignored. Government expenditure is therefore in the factor cost unit of account. Business costs and benefits are also assumed to be in the factor cost unit of account as businesses are free of indirect taxation because they can claim it back. An exception to this is fuel duty, which businesses cannot claim back.

Costs can be converted to (or from) market prices by multiplying (or dividing) by the indirect tax correction factor, (1+t), where t is 19.0% (equivalent to the average rate of indirect taxation in the UK economy).

Perceived costs are those which are actually experienced by users. Perceived costs are different for work and non-work trips because businesses can claim back VAT on purchases. Businesses cannot, however, claim back fuel duty and therefore this is included in their perceived cost. (where certain classes of PSV can claim back fuel duty this should be treated as a subsidy). Note that business users perceive costs in the factor cost unit of account, while consumers perceive costs in the market price unit of account.

9.5.7 Price Base Year

The price base year should also be the standard base year of 2010. All prices in the appraisal should be adjusted for inflation back to 2010 prices.

9.5.8 Model Base Year

The model base year will depend on the currency of the dataset used to develop the model. On the assumption that significant new datasets will be collected, the model base year is likely to be the current year (the year in which the surveys will be conducted).

9.5.9 Forecasts

In the case of a single intervention, forecasts are ideally required for the year of opening (see below) and a second 'forecast' year, some years after opening. In the case of a strategy or plan, forecasts are ideally required for at least the year of opening of each of the main elements of the option and for the future 'forecast year'. However, it may not always be practical to conduct forecasts for the opening years of every one of the main elements of an option. In such cases an appropriate common year should be chosen so that streams of costs and benefits can reasonably be inferred from a variety of different starting points.

9.5.10 Opening Year

In order to establish streams of costs and benefits for use in the CBA, it is necessary to assume an option opening year. This will be the year in which operating and maintenance costs begin to be incurred and typically the year in which the users begin to gain positive benefits from the option. Where elements of an option have different opening years, a reasonable approach to estimating cost and benefit streams without making an excessive number of model runs will be required. This will typically involve extrapolation and interpolation of the costs and benefits back from a common year for which the model is run.

9.5.11 Forecast Year

The 'forecast year' is the future year - typically 10 to 15 years after the opening year - for which the model is also run to generate single-year costs and benefits from which the streams of costs and benefits may be inferred. The forecast year may vary, depending on:

  • The timing at which problems are thought likely to become critical and in need of solution;
  • The kinds of solution considered appropriate and the time likely to be required for implementation; and
  • The availability of model input data on future trends, economic growth, and so on.

Thus, a study which is concerned with problems which are in need of urgent resolution in the next few years and for which traffic management solutions, for example, are considered appropriate, may use a forecast year only a few years away from the model base year. On the other hand, a study in which problems are thought likely to persist over a longer timeframe may use a forecast year 20 to 30 years away from the model base year.

A study may involve preparing forecasts and conducting analyses and appraisals for more than one forecast year. For example, if a strategy involves phased implementation of the options or if there is expected to be significant change in the rate of growth in user benefits over the appraisal period, then it is recommended that the model be run to generate forecasts for a set of time points which will enable the whole benefit and cost stream to be calculated.

9.5.12 Values of Time

The tables below provide the latest recommended values of time for application in most standard transport appraisals (all expressed in average 2010 values and prices). The data presented in the Tables have been taken from the Department for Transport's WebTAG 3.5.6)

The use of mode specific values could potentially increase the risk of not accounting for people who switch between modes. Where the number of people switching modes is high relative to the number of existing users it may be inappropriate to use the values below. Under these circumstances the practitioner should contact Transport Scotland for advice.

Table 9.7: Values of Working Time Per person (£ per hour)

Vehicle Occupant

Resource Cost

Perceived Cost

Market Price

Car driver

28.35

28.35

33.74

Car passenger

20.31

20.31

24.17

LGV (driver or passenger)

10.92

10.92

13.00

OGV (driver or passenger)

10.92

10.92

13.00

PSV driver

10.92

10.92

13.00

PSV passenger

21.69

21.69

25.81

Taxi driver

10.48

10.48

12.47

Taxi/minicab passenger

47.95

47.95

57.06

Rail passenger

39.65

39.65

47.18

Underground passenger

38.57

38.57

45.90

Walker

31.79

31.79

37.83

Cyclist

18.24

18.24

21.70

Motorcyclist

25.65

25.65

30.53

Average of all working persons

26.68

28.68

34.12

 

Table 9.8: Values of Non-Working Time Per person (£ per hour)

Vehicle Occupant

Resource Cost

Perceived Cost

Market Price

Commuting

5.43

6.46

6.46

Other

4.80

5.71

5.71

 

Practitioners should note that the values for non-working time (commuting and other) spent waiting for public transport is two and a half times the values presented in Table 9.8.

9.5.13 Forecast Growth in Values of Time

The recommended annual growth rates in values of time are presented in Table 9.9. These should be applied to work and non-work travel times over the appraisal period. The data presented in Table 9.9 has been taken from the Department for Transport's WebTAG 3.5.6)

Table 9.9: Forecast Growth in Working and Non-Working Values of Time

Year

Work VOT Growth (% pa)

Non-Work VOT Growth (% pa)

2003

3.12

2.49

2004

2.46

1.96

2005

1.42

1.14

2006

2.02

1.61

2007

2.78

2.22

2008

-1.77

-1.42

2009

-4.98

-4.01

2010

1.32

1.05

2011

-0.10

-0.08

2012

0.09

0.07

2013

1.28

1.02

2014

1.98

1.58

2015

2.30

1.84

2016

2.33

1.86

2017

2.13

1.70

2018

1.63

1.30

2019

1.64

1.31

2020

1.64

1.31

2021

1.85

1.48

2022

1.76

1.41

2023

1.77

1.42

2024

1.89

1.51

2025

1.80

1.44

2026

1.82

1.45

2027

1.83

1.46

2028

1.85

1.48

2029

1.87

1.49

2030

1.88

1.50

2031

1.90

1.52

2032

1.91

1.53

2033

2.03

1.62

2034

2.15

1.72

2035

2.15

1.72

2036

2.15

1.72

2037

2.08

1.66

2038

2.08

1.66

2039

2.08

1.66

2040

2.18

1.74

2041

2.18

1.74

2042

2.21

1.76

2043

2.31

1.84

2044

2.31

1.84

2045

2.21

1.76

2046

2.21

1.76

2047

2.14

1.71

2048

2.14

1.71

2049

2.14

1.71

2050

2.14

1.71

2051

2.04

1.63

2052

2.07

1.65

2053

2.07

1.65

2054

2.07

1.65

2055

2.07

1.65

2056

2.07

1.65

2057

2.08

1.66

2058

2.08

1.66

2059

2.09

1.67

2060

2.09

1.67

2061 onwards

2.17

1.73

9.5.14 Vehicle Occupancies

Car occupancy data extracted from the 1999-2001 National Travel Survey are shown in Table 9.10. This presents the sum of driver occupancy (always 1) and passenger occupancy.

Table 9.10: Car Occupancies (2000)

Journey Purpose

Weekday

Weekend Average

All Week Average

7am - 10am

10am - 4pm

4pm - 7pm

7pm - 7am

Weekday Average

Occupancy Per Vehicle Kilometre Travelled

Work

1.23

1.19

1.17

1.18

1.20

1.28

1.20

Commuting

1.16

1.15

1.13

1.13

1.14

1.14

1.14

Other

1.71

1.78

1.82

1.77

1.78

1.97

1.85

Average Car

1.45

1.68

1.60

1.52

1.61

1.88

1.68

Occupancy Per Trip

Work

1.26

1.19

1.20

1.21

1.21

1.30

1.22

Commuting

1.16

1.14

1.14

1.13

1.15

1.13

1.14

Other

1.72

1.70

1.76

1.71

1.72

1.96

1.79

Average Car

1.44

1.57

1.50

1.53

1.52

1.86

1.60

Occupancies for all other vehicles are illustrated in Table 9.11. Different occupancy figures for LGVs are available for a weekday and weekend. Only all week average occupancy figures are available for all other vehicles and these should be applied for all time periods.

Table 9.11: Other Vehicle Occupancies (2000)

Vehicle Type and Journey Purpose

Occupancy per vehicle Kilometre Travelled

Weekday Average

Weekend Average

All week Average

LGV

Work (freight)

1.20

1.26

1.20

Non Work (commuting and other)

1.46

2.03

1.59

Average LGV

1.23

1.35

1.25

OGV1 Work Only

1.00

1.00

1.00

OGV2 Work Only

1.00

1.00

1.00

PSV

Driver

1.00

1.00

1.00

Passenger

12.20

12.20

12.20

The forecast decline in car passenger occupancies (annual percentage change) to 2036 is shown in Table 9.12, below. After 2036 car passengers are assumed to remain constant. The occupancy rates for all other vehicles should be assumed to remain unchanged over time.

Table 9.12: Annual Percentage Change in Car Passenger Occupancy to 2036 (% per annum)

Journey Purpose

Weekday

Weekend Average

All Week Average

7am - 10am

10am - 4pm

4pm - 7pm

7pm - 7am

Weekday Average

Work

-0.48

-0.40

-0.62

-0.50

-0.44

-0.48

-0.45

Non-Work (commuting and other)

-0.67

-0.65

-0.53

-0.47

-0.59

-0.52

-0.56

9.5.15 Journey Purpose Splits

National Travel Survey (1999-2001) data is also used to produce journey purpose splits for work and non-work travel, based on distance travelled and the number of trips made. This allows the calculation of values of time per vehicle for the average vehicle. These journey purpose splits are assumed constant over time.

Table 9.13: Proportion of Travel in Work and Non-Work Time

Mode/Vehicle Type & Journey Purpose

Weekday

Weekend Average

All Week Average

7am - 10am

10am - 4pm

4pm - 7pm

7pm - 7am

Weekday Average

Percentage of Distance Travelled by Vehicles

Car

Work

18.1

19.9

13.0

12.3

16.4

3.2

13.1

Commuting

46.0

11.4

40.8

36.2

31.0

8.5

25.3

Other

35.9

68.7

46.2

51.5

52.5

88.3

61.6

LGV

Work (Freight)

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

Non-Work (Commuting & Other)

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

OGV1

Work

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

OGV2

Work

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

Percentage of Distance Travelled by Occupants

Car

Work

15.4

13.8

10.2

9.9

12.6

2.0

9.2

Commuting

38.3

8.1

32.2

29.1

23.9

5.1

18.0

Other

46.4

78.1

57.6

61.0

63.5

92.9

72.7

PSV

Work

3.9

2.0

3.9

5.7

3.4

1.5

2.9

Commuting

30.0

11.1

36.6

38.1

25.5

6.4

20.5

Other

66.1

86.9

59.5

56.2

71.1

92.0

76.6

Heavy Rail

Work

14.1

22.4

16.4

23.2

18.3

6.3

16.5

Commuting

51.9

10.2

55.9

53.1

43.7

4.3

37.8

Other

34.1

67.4

27.7

23.7

38.1

89.5

45.7

Light Rail

Work

1.9*

0.2*

1.8*

2.3*

1.3

0.4*

1.2

Commuting

82.4*

8.5*

75.7*

28.9*

50.1

23.3*

45.8

Other

15.7*

91.3*

22.5*

68.9*

48.6

76.3*

53.1

*Due to the small sample sizes involved these data should be treated with caution

Table 9.14: Proportion of Trips Made in Work and Non-Work Time

Mode/Vehicle Type & Journey Purpose

Weekday

Weekend Average

All Week Average

7am - 10am

10am - 4pm

4pm - 7pm

7pm - 7am

Weekday Average

Percentage of Vehicle Trips

Car

Work

6.8

8.3

5.5

3.6

6.5

1.7

5.0

Commuting

40.6

11.6

32.3

26.4

25.4

9.1

20.3

Other

52.7

80.1

62.2

70.0

68.1

89.3

74.7

LGV

Work (Freight)

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

88.0

Non-Work (Commuting & Other)

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

12.0

OGV1

Work

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

OGV2

Work

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

Percentage of Person Trips

Car

Work

5.2

2.2

4.1

1.2

4.7

1.1

3.4

Commuting

33.3

15.6

25.8

10.9

20.0

6.4

15.2

Other

61.5

82.2

70.1

87.9

75.3

92.5

81.4

PSV

Work

1.5

1.2

1.8

2.6

1.5

1.0

1.4

Commuting

41.7

10.6

43.0

47.4

26.9

12.4

24.3

Other

56.8

88.2

55.2

50.0

71.5

86.6

74.3

Heavy Rail

Work

6.7

13.6

6.7

8.8

8.3

2.8

7.6

Commuting

71.7

14.9

68.0

60.4

58.2

11.1

52.2

Other

21.6

71.5

25.4

30.8

33.5

86.1

40.3

Light Rail

Work

2.8*

0.7*

3.3*

5.3*

2.4

1.2*

2.2

Commuting

83.0*

10.8*

70.7*

23.7*

48.2

21.7*

43.8

Other

14.2*

88.5*

26.0*

71.1*

49.4

77.1*

54.0

* Due to the small sample sizes involved these data should be treated with caution

9.5.16 Values of Time Per Vehicle

The market price values of time per vehicle are presented in Table 9.15. These values are based on distance travelled and are calculated by multiplying the relevant data from Tables 9.7, 9.8, 9.10 and 9.11. Using national average vehicle proportions for 2010, the market price value of an average vehicle is £13.91 per hour, 2010 prices and values. The data presented in Table 9.15 has been taken from the Department for Transport's WebTAG 3.5.6).

Table 9.15: Market Price Values of Time Per Vehicle in 2010 (£ per hour, 2010 prices and values)

Vehicle Type & Journey Purpose

Weekday

Weekend Average

All Week Average

7am - 10am

10am - 4pm

4pm - 7pm

7pm - 7am

Weekday Average

Percentage of Vehicle Trips

Car

Work

39.04

38.15

37.60

37.88

38.37

40.19

38.36

Commuting

7.43

7.37

7.26

7.26

7.31

7.32

7.32

Other

9.50

9.88

10.15

9.90

9.91

10.97

10.30

Average Car

13.89

15.22

12.54

12.39

13.76

11.59

13.22

LGV

Work (Freight)

15.60

15.60

15.60

15.60

15.60

16.38

15.60

Non-Work (Commuting & Other)

8.66

8.66

8.66

8.66

8.66

12.03

9.43

Average LGV

14.77

14.77

14.77

14.77

14.77

15.86

14.86

OGV1

Working

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

OGV2

Working

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

13.00

PSV
(Occupants)

Work

25.28

19.30

25.28

30.95

23.71

17.72

22.13

Commuting

23.64

8.75

28.85

30.03

20.10

5.04

16.16

Other

46.05

60.54

41.45

39.15

49.53

64.09

53.36

Total

94.97

88.58

95.57

100.13

93.33

86.86

91.65

9.5.17 Vehicle Operating Costs (VOC)

The use of the road network by private cars and lorries generate operating costs for the user. Vehicle operating costs are defined as costs that vary with vehicle usage and are based on vehicle-miles travelled. These costs include fuel, tyres, oil, maintenance, repairs, and mileage-dependent depreciation. Clearly transport projects or policies can generate changes in vehicle operating costs by affecting the volume of car traffic, either through mode switching or induced traffic, and the speed and distance travelled through route changes.

9.5.18 Vehicle Operating Costs (Fuel and electricity)

Fuel consumption is estimated using a function of the form:

Mathematical Equation

Where:
consumption, expressed in litres per kilometre;
average speed in kilometres per hour; and
are parameters defined for each vehicle category.

Evidence of the energy consumption of electric cars is currently limited. At present, it should be assumed that energy consumption is proportional to distance by independent of speed (i.e. equivalent to a "b" parameter in the fuel consumption formula with the a, c and d parameters all zero). The appraisal of electric cars is a developing area and it is expected that speed related curves will be developed in the future.

The parameters needed to calculate the fuel/energy consumption element of VOCs are presented in Table 9.16. The fuel consumption parameter values are based on a 2010 vehicle fleet, whilst the electrical energy consumption values are based on 2011 values.

The data presented in Tables 9.16 - 9.25 has been taken from the Department for Transports WebTAG unit 3.5.6

Table 9.16: Fuel/Energy Consumption Formulae Parameter Values

Parameters

Vehicle Category

a

b

c

d

Fuel Consumption Parameter Values (litre per km, 2010)

Petrol Car

0.964022581

0.041448033

-4.54163E-05

2.01346E-06

Diesel Car

0.437094041

0.058616489

-0.00052488

4.12709E-06

Petrol LGV

1.556463336

0.064253318

-0.000744481

1.00552E-05

Diesel LGV

1.045268333

0.057901415

-0.000432895

8.0252E-06

OGV1

1.477368474

0.245615208

-0.003572413

3.0638E-05

OGV2

3.390702946

0.394379054

-0.004642285

3.59224E-05

PSV

4.115603124

0.306464813

-0.00420643

3.65263E-05

Energy Consumption Parameter Value (kWh per km, 2011)

Electric Car

0.12564236

Table 9.16 no longer provides consumption values for an 'average car', as united for electric cars (kWh) differ from the units for petrol and diesel cars (litres). However, it is possible to convert the consumption values into costs and estimate the fuel/energy per kilometre for an average car. Examples of this are given in Table 9.17 (which gives 2010 values, excluding electric cars) and Table 9.18 (which gives 2011 values, including electric cars and a combined average for petrol, diesel and electric cars).

Table 9.17: Fuel/Energy VOC Formulae Parameter values (2010 values and prices)

Parameters

Vehicle Category

a

b

c

d

Values excluding VAT (for vehicles in course of work)

Petrol Car

96.167

4.135

-0.00453

0.000201

Diesel Car

44.364

5.949

-0.05327

0.000419

Average Car

75.067

4.874

-0.02438

0.000290

Petrol LGV

155.266

6.410

-0.07427

0.001003

Diesel LGV

106.091

5.877

-0.04394

0.000815

Average LGV

108.973

5.908

-0.04571

0.000826

OGV1 (diesel)

149.948

24.929

-0.36259

0.003110

OGV2 (diesel)

344.145

40.028

-0.47118

0.003646

PSV (diesel)

417.720

31.105

-0.42694

0.003707

Values including VAT (for vehicles in course of other purposes)

Petrol Car

112.996

4.858

-0.00532

0.000236

Diesel Car

52.127

6.991

-0.06260

0.000492

Average Car

88.204

5.727

-0.02865

0.000340

Petrol LGV

182.438

7.531

-0.08726

0.001179

Diesel LGV

124.657

6.905

-0.05163

0.000957

Average LGV

128.043

6.942

-0.05371

0.000970

Note: In 2010 it is assumed there are no electric cars, so the 'Average Car' is an average over petrol and diesel.

Table 9.18: Fuel/Energy VOC Formulae Parameter values (2011 values and prices)

Parameters

Vehicle Category

a

b

c

d

Values excluding VAT (for vehicles in course of work)

Petrol Car

102.735

4.417

-0.00484

0.000215

Diesel Car

48.546

6.510

-0.05830

0.000458

Electric Car

0.000

1.732

-0.00000

0.000000

Average Car

79.423

5.315

-0.02780

0.000319

Petrol LGV

168.293

6.947

-0.08050

0.001087

Diesel LGV

115.668

6.407

-0.04790

0.000888

Average LGV

118.518

6.437

-0.04967

0.000899

OGV1 (diesel)

166.939

27.754

-0.40367

0.003462

OGV2 (diesel)

383.142

44.564

-0.52457

0.004059

PSV (diesel)

465.054

34.630

-0.47532

0.004127

Values including VAT (for vehicles in course of other purposes)

Petrol Car

123.282

5.300

-0.00581

0.000257

Diesel Car

58.255

7.812

-0.06996

0.000550

Electric Car

0.000

1.819

0.00000

0.000000

Average Car

95.308

6.378

-0.03336

0.000383

Petrol LGV

201.951

8.337

-0.09660

0.001305

Diesel LGV

138.802

7.689

-0.05748

0.001066

Average LGV

142.222

7.724

-0.05960

0.001079

Fuel Costs, Fuel Duty and VAT rates are shown in Table 9.19.

Table 9.19: Fuel Costs, Duty and VAT rates (2010 prices)

Year

Resource Cost

Duty

VAT

Petrol (p/litre)

Diesel (p/litre)

Electricity

Petrol (p/litre)

Diesel (p/litre)

Electric (p/kWh)

Petrol (%)

Diesel (%)

Electric (%)

Road (p/kWh)

Rail (p/kWh)

2002 (actual)

20.39

22.46

55.92

55.92

17.5

17.5

2003 (actual)

22.39

24.06

55.02

55.02

17.5

17.5

2004 (actual)

24.87

26.31

54.80

54.80

17.5

17.5

2005 (actual)

30.76

34.41

53.62

53.62

17.5

17.5

2006 (actual)

33.91

37.30

52.06

52.06

17.5

17.5

2007 (actual)

34.08

36.21

52.68

52.68

17.5

17.5

2008 (actual)

42.83

51.75

52.82

52.82

17.3

17.3

2009 (actual)

33.16

37.01

55.95

55.95

15

15

2010 (actual)

42.57

44.31

12.35

6.18

57.19

57.19

0.00

17.5

17.5

5

2011 (actual)

51.95

56.11

13.78

8.62

56.89

56.89

0.00

20

20

5

2012

53.62

59.64

14.78

8.98

56.47

56.47

0.00

20

20

5

2013

54.13

60.21

15.56

9.59

57.96

57.96

0.00

20

20

5

2014

54.65

60.78

16.05

9.48

57.96

57.96

0.00

20

20

5

2015

55.18

61.36

16.20

9.55

58.58

58.58

0.00

20

20

5

2016

55.71

61.95

16.74

9.67

59.44

59.44

0.00

20

20

5

2017

56.25

62.54

17.03

9.73

60.16

60.16

0.00

20

20

5

2018

56.79

63.14

16.78

9.52

60.73

60.73

0.00

20

20

5

2019

57.34

63.74

17.30

9.65

61.16

61.16

0.00

20

20

5

2020

57.90

64.35

17.96

9.97

61.44

61.44

0.00

20

20

5

2021

58.46

64.97

18.52

10.58

61.56

61.56

0.00

20

20

5

2022

59.02

65.59

18.78

10.96

61.68

61.68

0.00

20

20

5

2023

59.59

66.22

18.79

11.21

61.80

61.80

0.00

20

20

5

2024

60.17

66.85

19.27

11.94

61.92

61.92

0.00

20

20

5

2025

60.75

67.50

19.74

12.42

62.04

62.04

0.00

20

20

5

2026

61.34

68.15

19.92

12.55

62.16

62.16

0.00

20

20

5

2027

61.94

68.80

20.32

12.93

62.28

62.28

0.00

20

20

5

2028

62.54

69.47

20.45

13.09

62.40

62.40

0.00

20

20

5

2029

63.15

70.14

20.34

13.20

62.52

62.52

0.00

20

20

5

2030

63.76

70.81

20.60

13.47

62.65

62.65

0.00

20

20

5

Table 9.20: Resource cost of electricity from 2031 (2010 prices)

Year

Road (p/kWh)

Rail (p/kWh)

Year

Road (p/kWh)

Rail (p/kWh)

2031

20.60

13.47

2066

19.39

12.26

2032

20.56

13.44

2067

19.39

12.27

2033

20.50

13.37

2068

19.40

12.27

2034

20.41

13.28

2069

19.41

12.28

2035

20.29

13.16

2070

19.41

12.28

2036

20.13

13.00

2071

19.41

12.29

2037

19.95

12.82

2072

19.42

12.29

2038

19.73

12.61

2073

19.42

12.29

2039

19.49

12.36

2074

19.42

12.29

2040

19.22

12.09

2075

19.43

12.30

2041

19.22

12.09

2076

19.43

12.30

2042

19.22

12.09

2077

19.43

12.30

2043

19.22

12.09

2078

19.43

12.30

2044

19.22

12.09

2079

19.42

12.30

2045

19.22

12.09

2080

19.42

12.29

2046

19.21

12.08

2081

19.42

12.29

2047

19.21

12.08

2082

19.42

12.29

2048

19.20

12.07

2083

19.42

12.29

2049

19.19

12.06

2084

19.41

12.29

2050

19.17

12.04

2085

19.41

12.28

2051

19.19

12.06

2086

19.41

12.28

2052

19.21

12.08

2087

19.40

12.28

2053

19.22

12.09

2088

19.40

12.27

2054

19.24

12.11

2089

19.39

12.27

2055

19.25

12.13

2090

19.39

12.26

2056

19.27

12.14

2091

19.39

12.26

2057

19.29

12.16

2092

19.38

12.25

2058

19.30

12.17

2093

19.38

12.25

2059

19.31

12.19

2094

19.37

12.24

2060

19.33

12.20

2095

19.36

12.24

2061

19.34

12.21

2096

19.36

12.23

2062

19.35

12.22

2097

19.35

12.22

2063

19.36

12.23

2098

19.35

12.22

2064

19.37

12.24

2099

19.34

12.21

2065

19.38

12.25

2100

19.33

12.20

The resource cost of fuel VOCs is net of indirect taxation. The market price is gross of indirect taxation and is therefore the sum of the resource cost and fuel duty, plus VAT (market price= [resource cost + fuel duty] x [1+VAT]). In work time the perceived cost of fuel VOCs is the cost perceived by businesses. Businesses are generally viewed as perceiving costs in the factor cost unit of account as most business costs are free of indirect taxation because they can claim it back. However, businesses cannot reclaim fuel duty and therefore the perceived cost of fuel VOCs in work time is equal to the resource cost plus fuel duty. In non-work time, the perceived cost of fuel VOCs is the cost as perceived by the individual consumer. Consumers perceive costs in the market price unit of account and therefore the perceived value of fuel VOCs in non-working time is equal to the market price.

Values for fuel duty and VAT in Table 19.9 take account of all changes announced in the 2012 Budget Report (HMT March 2012). These are:

  • A 3.02p per litre increase in fuel duty from 57.95p per litre to 60.97p per litre on 1 August 2012
  • Increases in line with RPI on 1 April each year from 2013 onwards.

The actual price of a unit of electricity may vary according to the type of electricity used (domestic, commercial or industrial) which in itself will depend on where electric cars are recharged. We would expect much of the electricity for electric cars to be charged at the domestic rate. At the same time, the rail industry pays a much lower price for electricity than domestic users.

Beyond 2030, the electricity prices for both car and rail are assumed to vary according to the change in carbon cost only. For petrol and diesel beyond 2030, both the resource and duty prices are forecast to grow at a rate of 0.195% per year.

Information on the rates of fuel duty to be applied in the calculation of rail fuel operating costs can be found in Section 9.5.22 Rail Operating Costs.

Table 9.21 shows the forecast proportion of the car and LGV fleet using petrol, diesel or mains electricity used to calculate average car and LGV values. Values for years between 2005 and 2029 that are not shown in the table should be estimated using linear interpolation between the two closest years. Values for 2031 onwards should be assumed to be held at 2030 levels. With electric cars still in the early stages of development, and uncertainty over the rate of progression in battery technology (a key barrier to progress) there is necessarily a large margin of error around any forecast take up of electric vehicles. As such this projection should be seen as one of a range of potential development pathways and any particular sensitivity to the pathway given out here noted in the analysis.

Table 9.21: Proportion of cars and LGV vehicle kms using petrol, diesel or mains electricity (%)

Year

Cars

LGVs

Petrol

Diesel

Electric

Petrol

Diesel

2004

73.28

26.72

0.00

11.07

88.93

2010

59.27

40.73

0.00

5.86

94.14

2015

47.97

51.87

0.16

3.64

96.36

2020

43.70

55.33

0.96

1.89

98.11

2025

44.41

53.05

2.54

1.04

98.96

2030

44.46

50.23

5.31

0.79

99.21

9.5.19 Rates of Change in Fuel VOCs

There are two causes of changes in fuel VOC over time: improvements in vehicle efficiency and changes in the cost of fuel. For cars, changes in fuel VOCs also reflect changes in the proportion of traffic using either petrol, diesel or mains electricity.

Vehicle efficiency assumptions are illustrated in Table 9.22. These figures show changes in fuel consumption and therefore negative figures indicate an improvement in vehicle efficiency.

Table 9.22: Assumed Vehicle Fuel Efficiency Improvements

Year

Change in Vehicle Efficiency (% pa)

Petrol Car

Diesel Car

Electric Car

Petrol LGV

Diesel LGV

OGV1

OGV2

PSV

2006-2007

-0.42 (actual)

-0.49 (actual)

-0.01

0.00

-1.23

-1.23

0.00

2007-2008

-1.05 (actual)

-1.07 (actual)

-0.01

0.00

-1.23

-1.23

0.00

2008-2009

-1.78 (actual)

-0.92 (actual)

-1.35 (actual)

-1.23 (actual)

-1.23

-1.23

0.00

2009-2010

-1.43 (actual)

-1.63 (actual)

-0.34 (actual)

-1.80 (actual)

0

0

0.00

2010-2015

-2.09

-1.71

-0.11

-0.66

-2.07

0.00

0.00

0.00

2015-2020

-3.72

-2.22

-0.31

-1.38

-2.34

0.00

0.00

0.00

2020-2025

-3.63

-2.62

-0.71

-3.07

-2.19

0.00

0.00

0.00

2025-2030

-2.10

-2.10

-1.19

-2.95

-1.30

0.00

0.00

0.00

2030 - 2035

-0.74

-0.96

-0.26

-0.86

-0.57

0.00

0.00

0.00

As with consumption values noted earlier, values for an average car are no longer provided as petrol, diesel and electric cars do not have common units. Table 9.23 shows how the parameters to calculate fuel/energy cost per kilometre changes through time for an average car and an average LGV.

Table 9.23: Average Car/LGV Fuel/Energy Cost Formulae Parameter Values (2010 prices)

Parameters

Vehicle Category

a

b

c

d

Average Car, excluding VAT (for travel in course of work)

2010

75.067

4.874

-0.0244

0.000290

2015

72.284

5.384

-0.0322

0.000334

2020

62.367

4.975

-0.0317

0.000314

2025

54.095

4.351

-0.0274

0.000272

2030

49.069

3.957

-0.0241

0.000242

Average LGV, excluding VAT (for travel in course of Work)

2010

108.973

5.908

-0.0457

0.000826

2015

115.050

6.285

-0.0480

0.000876

2020

106.380

5.848

-0.0443

0.000813

2025

97.508

5.380

-0.0405

0.000747

2030

93.979

5.187

-0.0390

0.000720

Average Car, including VAT (for travel in course of other purposes)

2010

88.204

5.727

-0.0287

0.000340

2015

86.741

6.460

-0.0386

0.000401

2020

74.840

5.967

-0.0381

0.000376

2025

64.914

5.212

-0.0329

0.000326

2030

58.883

4.730

-0.0290

0.000290

Average LGV, including VAT (for travel in course of other purposes)

2010

128.043

6.942

-0.0537

0.000970

2015

138.060

7.542

-0.0577

0.001051

2020

127.657

7.018

-0.0531

0.000975

2025

117.010

6.456

-0.0486

0.000896

2030

112.775

6.224

-0.0468

0.000864

9.5.20 Vehicle Operating Costs (Non-Fuel)

Non-fuel-related costs include the costs of oil, tires, maintenance and repairs, depreciation and capital saving for vehicles in working time.

Non-fuel VOCs are calculated using the following formula;

Mathematical Equation

Where;
C = cost in pence per kilometre travelled,
V = average link speed in kilometres per hour,
a1 = a parameter for distance related costs defined for each vehicle category,
b1 = a parameter for vehicle capital saving defined for each vehicle category (only relevant to working vehicles).

Currently parameter a1 takes the same value for petrol and diesel vehicles. For electric vehicles, the evidence is very weak, but suggests that the costs are lower because there are fewer moving parts that are likely to wear out with mileage. There is currently no evidence to confirm whether the a1 parameter differs by trip purpose for electric cars. There is also no evidence regarding the b1 parameter for electric cars in-work. For the present it will be assumed that the vehicle capital saving for electric cars will be the same as for petrol/diesel cars.

Table 9.24 presents the required parameters to calculate the non-fuel vehicle operating costs.

Table 9.24: Non-Fuel Resource VOCs, 2010 (2010 prices)

Vehicle Category

Parameter Values

a1 pence/km

b1 pence/km

Work Petrol

4.966

135.946

Work Diesel

4.966

135.946

Work Electric

1.157

135.946

Non-Work Petrol

3.846

Non-Work Diesel

3.846

Non-Work Electric

1.157

LGV

Work

7.213

47.113

Non-Work (commuting and other)

7.213

Average LGV

7.213

41.458

OGV1

6.714

263.817

OGV2

13.061

508.525

PSV

30.461

694.547

Non-fuel VOCs are assumed to remain constant in real terms over the forecast period; however parameters for an average car vary through time (owing to changes in the proportion of electric vehicles) and are given in Table 9.25.

Table 9.25: Non-Fuel Resource VOCs through time (2010 prices)

Year

Work Car

Non-Work Car

Average Car

a1 pence/km

b1 pence/hr

a1 pence/km

b1 pence/hr

a1 pence/km

b1 pence/hr

2010

4.966

135.946

3.846

0.000

3.992

17.809

2015

4.960

135.946

3.841

0.000

3.988

17.809

2020

4.929

135.946

3.820

0.000

3.965

17.809

2025

4.869

135.946

3.777

0.000

3.920

17.809

2030

4.764

135.946

3.703

0.000

3.842

17.809

9.5.21 Bus Operating Costs

In a standard appraisal of a road scheme buses should be treated as part of the traffic flow, and the operating cost formulae (described above) are applied, using the appropriate parameter values for PSVs. In a multi-modal study, however, different options may result not only in faster or slower running times for existing bus services, but in the need for more or different levels and patterns of bus service provision. In these cases, the impact of options on the costs of bus service provision have to be considered in more detail.

9.5.22 Rail Operating Costs

Information on rail operating costs can be obtained through discussion with Transport Scotland.

9.5.23 Rail Appraisal - Road Network Effects

Transport Scotland recommend that impacts on the wider transport network are assessed with a multi-modal transport model. However, it recognises that in some cases the cost of developing such a model cannot be justified as being in keeping with the principle of proportionality in STAG appraisal. In such cases suitable approximations of the impact on the road network should be applied and identified separately in the TEE table.

In many cases, approximate values can be obtained through taking skims of existing road network models for the local area. The Department for Transport has also provided estimates for the impact of marginal changes to car flows on the road network based on data from the NTM. Practitioners should make use of the methods and values set out in Unit 3.9.5 of WebTAG where local models of the road network are unavailable.

It should be noted that, consistent with STAG guidance under the Environment Criterion, monetised values for journey ambience, local air pollution, or noise should not be included in the AST.

9.6 Reporting

It is important that practitioners provide clear and concise details of the impacts which are calculated during Part 2 Appraisal under the Economy Criterion in the STAG Report. For the TEE analysis, a statement of key appraisal parameters should be made and the key components of the present value of benefits should be presented and described - Travel time, User charges, Vehicle Operating Costs and Quality/Reliability benefits (where appropriate). This should be complemented by the presentation and discussion of the distribution of journey time (dis-) benefits by size, the product of the analysis outlined in section 9.2.2.1.

A tabular presentation of results is expected in the Part 2 AST with supporting information provided to outline the basis for the quantitative impacts calculated. Calculated WEBS and EALI benefits should be presented clearly in the same Part 2 AST supplemented by spatial analysis of the impacts of a scheme where possible (most likely, using GIS). Where no WEB or EALI impacts are expected this should be stated clearly.

Footnotes

1. Laird J., Review of Economic Assessment in Rural Transport Appraisal, (2009), http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Publications/2009/10/29110947/0
2. Transport, Wider Economic Benefits and Impacts on GDP, Department for Transport (2006)
3. Transport, Wider Economic Benefits and Impacts on GDP, Department for Transport (2006)
4. Laird J., Review of Economic Assessment in Rural Transport Appraisal, (2009), http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Publications/2009/10/29110947/0